763 results on '"Strong reciprocity"'
Search Results
2. Research on Repeated Quantum Games with Public Goods under Strong Reciprocity.
- Author
-
Sun, Simo, Shu, Yadong, Pi, Jinxiu, and Zhou, Die
- Subjects
- *
PUBLIC goods , *RECIPROCITY (Psychology) , *QUANTUM entanglement , *INDOOR games , *GREEN technology , *GAMES - Abstract
We developed a repeated quantum game of public goods by using quantum entanglement and strong reciprocity mechanisms. Utilizing the framework of quantum game analysis, a comparative investigation incorporating both entangled and non-entangled states reveals that the player will choose a fully cooperative strategy when the expected cooperation strategy of the competitor exceeds a certain threshold. When the entanglement of states is not considered, the prisoner's dilemma still exists, and the cooperating party must bear the cost of defactoring the quantum strategy themselves; when considering the entanglement of states, the benefits of both parties in the game are closely related, forming a community of benefits. By signing a strong reciprocity contract, the degree of cooperation between the game parties can be considered using the strong reciprocity entanglement contract mechanism. The party striving to cooperate does not have to bear the risk of the other party's defector, and to some extent, it can solve the prisoner's dilemma problem. Finally, taking the public goods green planting industry project as an example, by jointly entrusting a third party to determine and sign a strong reciprocity entanglement contract, both parties can ensure a complete quantum strategy to maximize cooperation and achieve Pareto optimality, ultimately enabling the long-term and stable development of the public goods industry project. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2023
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
3. 利他的罰と感染予防規範逸脱者・感染者に対する攻撃との 関連の検討.
- Author
-
真島 理恵 and 木村 多聞
- Abstract
Faced with the COVID-19 pandemic, some people in Japan have started voluntarily and anonymously policing others who do not engage in infection prevention behaviors. Such extreme ways of enforcing norms to prevent the spread of COVID-19 may have serious consequences since the targets essentially become victims of kangaroo courts. This study examined the possibility that such aggressive behavior is based on strong reciprocity, which is one of the proposed mechanisms that may have made humans super-cooperative. An online survey measured several aspects of strong reciprocity (e.g., altruistic punishment, altruistic rewarding), impressions of and behavioral intentions toward those who violate infection prevention norms and COVID-19 patients, and the degree to which the respondents engaged in infection prevention behaviors. The results revealed that the tendency to engage in altruistic punishment had a positive effect on aggression toward those who violated infection prevention norms and COVID-19 patients only among those who engaged in infection prevention behaviors. This suggests that altruistic punishment may promote aggression toward those who violate infection prevention norms in people who follow such norms. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2023
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
4. Research on Repeated Quantum Games with Public Goods under Strong Reciprocity
- Author
-
Simo Sun, Yadong Shu, Jinxiu Pi, and Die Zhou
- Subjects
public goods ,repeated game ,strong reciprocity ,quantum entanglement ,Pareto ,Mathematics ,QA1-939 - Abstract
We developed a repeated quantum game of public goods by using quantum entanglement and strong reciprocity mechanisms. Utilizing the framework of quantum game analysis, a comparative investigation incorporating both entangled and non-entangled states reveals that the player will choose a fully cooperative strategy when the expected cooperation strategy of the competitor exceeds a certain threshold. When the entanglement of states is not considered, the prisoner’s dilemma still exists, and the cooperating party must bear the cost of defactoring the quantum strategy themselves; when considering the entanglement of states, the benefits of both parties in the game are closely related, forming a community of benefits. By signing a strong reciprocity contract, the degree of cooperation between the game parties can be considered using the strong reciprocity entanglement contract mechanism. The party striving to cooperate does not have to bear the risk of the other party’s defector, and to some extent, it can solve the prisoner’s dilemma problem. Finally, taking the public goods green planting industry project as an example, by jointly entrusting a third party to determine and sign a strong reciprocity entanglement contract, both parties can ensure a complete quantum strategy to maximize cooperation and achieve Pareto optimality, ultimately enabling the long-term and stable development of the public goods industry project.
- Published
- 2023
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
5. Strong Reciprocity
- Author
-
Paál, Tünde, Beaver, Kevin, Section editor, Shackelford, Todd K, editor, and Weekes-Shackelford, Viviana A, editor
- Published
- 2021
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
6. Decoupling cooperation and punishment in humans shows that punishment is not an altruistic trait.
- Author
-
Burton-Chellew, Maxwell N. and Guérin, Claire
- Subjects
- *
PUNISHMENT , *COOPERATION , *EVOLUTIONARY models , *HUMAN beings - Abstract
Economic experiments have suggested that cooperative humans will altruistically match local levels of cooperation (conditional cooperation) and pay to punish non-cooperators (altruistic punishment). Evolutionary models have suggested that if altruists punish non-altruists this could favour the evolution of costly helping behaviours (cooperation) among strangers. An oftenkey requirement is that helping behaviours and punishing behaviours form one single conjoined trait (strong reciprocity). Previous economics experiments have provided support for the hypothesis that punishment and cooperation form one conjoined, altruistically motivated, trait. However, such a conjoined trait may be evolutionarily unstable, and previous experiments have confounded a fear of being punished with being surrounded by cooperators, two factors that could favour cooperation. Here, we experimentally decouple the fear of punishment from a cooperative environment and allowcooperation and punishment behaviour to freely separate (420 participants). We show, that if a minority of individuals is made immune to punishment, they (i) learn to stop cooperating on average despite being surrounded by high levels of cooperation, contradicting the idea of conditional cooperation and (ii) often continue to punish, 'hypocritically', showing that cooperation and punishment do not form one, altruistically motivated, linked trait. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2021
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
7. North’s Theory of Cultural Evolution
- Author
-
Krul, Matthijs, Cohen, Avi, Series Editor, Harcourt, Geoffrey Colin, Series Editor, Kriesler, Peter, Series Editor, Toporowski, Jan, Series Editor, and Krul, Matthijs
- Published
- 2018
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
8. The Image of Humans
- Author
-
Conrad, Christian A., Conrad, Christian A., and Webb, Danica, Translated by
- Published
- 2018
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
9. The Logic and Location of Strong Reciprocity: Anthropological and Philosophical Considerations
- Author
-
Kiper, Jordan, Sosis, Richard, Li, Meng, editor, and Tracer, David P., editor
- Published
- 2017
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
10. Altruistic punishment in modern intentional communities.
- Author
-
Qirko, Hector
- Abstract
Evolutionists studying human cooperation disagree about how to best explain it. One view is that humans are predisposed to engage in costly cooperation and punishment of free-riders as a result of culture/gene coevolution via group selection. Alternatively, some researchers argue that context-specific cognitive mechanisms associated with traditional neo-Darwinian self- and kin-maximization models sufficiently explain all aspects of human cooperation and punishment. There has been a great deal of research testing predictions derived from both positions; still, researchers generally agree that more naturalistic data are needed to complement mathematical modeling and laboratory and field experiments. Most of these data have been obtained from small-scale forager and other societies, but modern intentional communities offer another productive source of information. This exploratory study describes context-specific patterns of punishment in 46 American intentional communities that cast doubt on the prediction that people are predisposed to punish free-riders in naturalistic interactions. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2020
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
11. Reciprocal Altruism
- Author
-
Payne, Kenneth and Payne, Kenneth
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
12. Punishment Strategies across Societies: Conventional Wisdoms Reconsidered
- Author
-
Ramzi Suleiman and Yuval Samid
- Subjects
cooperation ,punishment ,antisocial punishment ,public goods ,strong reciprocity ,Technology ,Social Sciences - Abstract
Experiments using the public goods game have repeatedly shown that in cooperative social environments, punishment makes cooperation flourish, and withholding punishment makes cooperation collapse. In less cooperative social environments, where antisocial punishment has been detected, punishment was detrimental to cooperation. The success of punishment in enhancing cooperation was explained as deterrence of free riders by cooperative strong reciprocators, who were willing to pay the cost of punishing them, whereas in environments in which punishment diminished cooperation, antisocial punishment was explained as revenge by low cooperators against high cooperators suspected of punishing them in previous rounds. The present paper reconsiders the generality of both explanations. Using data from a public goods experiment with punishment, conducted by the authors on Israeli subjects (Study 1), and from a study published in Science using sixteen participant pools from cities around the world (Study 2), we found that: 1. The effect of punishment on the emergence of cooperation was mainly due to contributors increasing their cooperation, rather than from free riders being deterred. 2. Participants adhered to different contribution and punishment strategies. Some cooperated and did not punish (‘cooperators’); others cooperated and punished free riders (‘strong reciprocators’); a third subgroup punished upward and downward relative to their own contribution (‘norm-keepers’); and a small sub-group punished only cooperators (‘antisocial punishers’). 3. Clear societal differences emerged in the mix of the four participant types, with high-contributing pools characterized by higher ratios of ‘strong reciprocators’, and ‘cooperators’, and low-contributing pools characterized by a higher ratio of ‘norm keepers’. 4. The fraction of ‘strong reciprocators’ out of the total punishers emerged as a strong predictor of the groups’ level of cooperation and success in providing the public goods.
- Published
- 2021
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
13. Rationality and the Green Revolution
- Author
-
Tucker, Bram, Sear, Rebecca, Series editor, Gibson, Mhairi A., editor, and Lawson, David W., editor
- Published
- 2014
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
14. Investigating the funding success factors affecting reward-based crowdfunding projects.
- Author
-
Yeh, Tsai-Lien, Chen, Tser-Yieth, and Lee, Cheng-Chun
- Subjects
LOGISTIC regression analysis ,SUCCESS ,REGRESSION analysis - Abstract
The issue of which factors influence the success or failure of crowdfunding projects is a critical topic, as it can bring founders sufficient financial support to realise their ideal innovation. We present a useful framework for two aspects of marketing (attraction-promotion and cognition-promotion) and four related factors to foster the success of reward-based crowdfunding ventures. We investigate this issue by analysing data collected from 323 funding projects from four crowdfunding platforms in Taiwan and Japan. We found that the cognition-promotion aspect obviously influenced funding success, because the factors it encompasses – signalling (including founder response, founder updates frequency and having a formal website) and kindness (including donation to other projects and rewarding sponsors) – are all significant in the logistic regression model. Regarding the attraction-promotion aspect, we found that the past experiences of the founder in terms of the attention factor do not influence funding success. Our study contributes to the literature on crowdfunding discussion platforms and engagement, and our empirical results provide a comprehensive message to the founders and sponsors of crowdfunding platforms. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2019
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
15. Contextualised strong reciprocity explains selfless cooperation despite selfish intuitions and weak social heuristics
- Author
-
A. John Maule, Ozan Isler, Chris Starmer, and Simon Gächter
- Subjects
Adult ,Male ,provision dilemma ,Science ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Control (management) ,cooperation ,Strong reciprocity ,Article ,03 medical and health sciences ,Cognition ,Perception ,Human behaviour ,0502 economics and business ,Data_FILES ,Psychology ,Heuristics ,Humans ,economic experiments ,Cooperative Behavior ,050207 economics ,Positive economics ,Social Behavior ,030304 developmental biology ,media_common ,conditional cooperation ,0303 health sciences ,Multidisciplinary ,strong reciprocity ,social heuristics hypothesis ,05 social sciences ,Social dilemma ,Deliberation ,social dilemmas ,Preference ,maintenance dilemma ,Dilemma ,Medicine ,Female ,self-control hypothesis ,Social heuristics ,Intuition - Abstract
PROJECT PAGE for Isler, O., Gächter, S., Maule, A.J., Starmer, C., 2021. Contextualised strong reciprocity explains selfless cooperation despite selfish intuitions and weak social heuristics. Scientific Reports 11, 13868. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-021-93412-4 ABSTRACT: Humans frequently cooperate for collective benefit, even in one-shot social dilemmas. This provides a challenge for theories of cooperation. Two views focus on intuitions but offer conflicting explanations. The Social Heuristics Hypothesis argues that people with selfish preferences rely on cooperative intuitions and predicts that deliberation reduces cooperation. The Self-Control Account emphasizes control over selfish intuitions and is consistent with strong reciprocity—a preference for conditional cooperation in one-shot dilemmas. Here, we reconcile these explanations with each other as well as with strong reciprocity. We study one-shot cooperation across two main dilemma contexts, provision and maintenance, and show that cooperation is higher in provision than maintenance. Using time-limit manipulations, we experimentally study the cognitive processes underlying this robust result. Supporting the Self-Control Account, people are intuitively selfish in maintenance, with deliberation increasing cooperation. In contrast, consistent with the Social Heuristics Hypothesis, deliberation tends to increase the likelihood of free-riding in provision. Contextual differences between maintenance and provision are observed across additional measures: reaction time patterns of cooperation; social dilemma understanding; perceptions of social appropriateness; beliefs about others’ cooperation; and cooperation preferences. Despite these dilemma-specific asymmetries, we show that preferences, coupled with beliefs, successfully predict the high levels of cooperation in both maintenance and provision dilemmas. While the effects of intuitions are context-dependent and small, the widespread preference for strong reciprocity is the primary driver of one-shot cooperation. We advance the Contextualised Strong Reciprocity account as a unifying framework and consider its implications for research and policy.
- Published
- 2022
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
16. Rationality and Deceit: Why Rational Egoism Cannot Make Us Moral
- Author
-
Rosas, Alejandro, Musschenga, Bert, editor, and van Harskamp, Anton, editor
- Published
- 2013
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
17. Resource Theory and Restoration: What is Restored in Restorative Justice?
- Author
-
Cohen, Ronald L., Törnblom, Kjell, editor, and Kazemi, Ali, editor
- Published
- 2012
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
18. Mind the Gap: Cooperative Breeding and the Evolution of Our Unique Features
- Author
-
van Schaik, Carel P., Burkart, Judith M., Kappeler, Peter M., editor, and Silk, Joan, editor
- Published
- 2010
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
19. Strong reciprocity and strong consistency in pairwise comparison matrix with fuzzy elements.
- Author
-
Ramík, Jaroslav
- Subjects
PAIRED comparisons (Mathematics) ,DECISION theory ,MATRICES (Mathematics) ,RECIPROCITY theorems ,ABELIAN groups ,FUZZY logic - Abstract
The decision making problem considered in this paper is to rank n alternatives from the best to the worst, using the information given by the decision maker in the form of an n×n
pairwise comparison matrix. Here, we deal with pairwise comparison matrices with fuzzy elements. Fuzzy elements of the pairwise comparison matrix are applied whenever the decision maker is not sure about the value of his/her evaluation of the relative importance of elements in question. We investigate pairwise comparison matrices with elements from abelian linearly ordered group (alo-group) over a real interval. The concept of reciprocity and consistency of pairwise comparison matrices with fuzzy elements have been already studied in the literature. Here, we define stronger concepts, namely the strong reciprocity and strong consistency of pairwise comparison matrices with fuzzy intervals as the matrix elements (PCF matrices), derive the necessary and sufficient conditions for strong reciprocity and strong consistency and investigate their properties as well as some consequences to the problem of ranking the alternatives. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR] - Published
- 2018
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
20. Social Identities in Experimental Economics
- Author
-
Warren, Nicolas de, editor, Moran, Dermot, editor, and Schmid, Hans Bernhard, editor
- Published
- 2009
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
21. Implications of Behavioural Game Theory for Neoclassical Economic Theory
- Author
-
Gintis, Herbert, Kornai, János, editor, Mátyás, László, editor, and Roland, Gérard, editor
- Published
- 2008
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
22. Reciprocal altruism: 30 years later
- Author
-
Trivers, Robert, Kappeler, Peter M., editor, and van Schaik, Carel P., editor
- Published
- 2006
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
23. Povaha ľudskej spolupráce a význam altruistického trestania: Ako sa ľudia správajú v laboratóriu a v teréne?
- Author
-
Martin Hulín
- Subjects
economic games ,altruistic punishment ,strong reciprocity ,cooperation ,hunter-gatherers ,conflict resolution ,symbolic sanctions ,Anthropology ,GN1-890 - Abstract
There is an increasing interest of behavioral economists in the last decades in studying the nature of human cooperation and morality. Several economic games of social dilemmas have been developed to this end. Based on the results of these games, important conclusions are made about human cooperation. Since people in these games all over the world do not behave completely selfishly and give away money, it is taken as demonstrating other important motivations. When people are given the opportunity to punish free-riders, this increases cooperation, which is again interpreted in the sense of altruistic punishment (strong reciprocity) that is considered a key factor in sustaining cooperation. However, these results are in contrast with the anthropological literature on hunter-gatherers’ cooperation, which highlights other important factors sustaining cooperation, such as the possibility to choose partners, and symbolic and coalitional sanctions (weak reciprocity). The aim of the research is to critically analyze these contrasts and illustrate some aspects of cooperation (conflict resolution, dealing with cheaters, and the role of reputation) from the author’s own research of mutual aid among peasants in Serbia.
- Published
- 2014
24. The Function of Assertion and Social Norms
- Author
-
Graham, Peter J. and Goldberg, Sanford, book editor
- Published
- 2020
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
25. Just Hierarchy between States: On the Need for Reciprocity
- Author
-
Bell, Daniel A., author and Pei, Wang, author
- Published
- 2020
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
26. Religion, parochialism and intuitive cooperation
- Author
-
Onurcan Yilmaz, Ozan Isler, A. John Maule, and Yılmaz, Onurcan
- Subjects
Religion and Psychology ,Social Psychology ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Decision Making ,Experimental and Cognitive Psychology ,Strong reciprocity ,PREFERENCES ,03 medical and health sciences ,Behavioral Neuroscience ,Parochialism ,0302 clinical medicine ,Game Theory ,Collective identity ,Reciprocity (social psychology) ,Heuristics ,Humans ,CONDITIONAL COOPERATION ,Interpersonal Relations ,Cooperative Behavior ,030304 developmental biology ,media_common ,Motivation ,0303 health sciences ,SOCIAL HEURISTICS ,Prisoner Dilemma ,RECIPROCITY ,Deliberation ,SELF-CONTROL ,INCENTIVES ,EVOLUTION ,Dilemma ,Incentive ,INFERENCE ,GOD-CONCEPTS ,Psychology ,Social psychology ,Social heuristics ,BEHAVIOR ,Intuition ,030217 neurology & neurosurgery - Abstract
Religions promote cooperation, but they can also be divisive. Is religious cooperation intuitively parochial against atheists? Evidence supporting the social heuristics hypothesis (SHH) suggests that cooperation is intuitive, independent of religious group identity. We tested this prediction in a one-shot prisoner’s dilemma game, where 1,280 practising Christian believers were paired with either a coreligionist or an atheist and where time limits were used to increase reliance on either intuitive or deliberated decisions. We explored another dual-process account of cooperation, the self-control account (SCA), which suggests that visceral reactions tend to be selfish and that cooperation requires deliberation. We found evidence for religious parochialism but no support for SHH’s prediction of intuitive cooperation. Consistent with SCA but requiring confirmation in future studies, exploratory analyses showed that religious parochialism involves decision conflict and concern for strong reciprocity and that deliberation promotes cooperation independent of religious group identity. The Stage 1 protocol for this Registered Report was accepted in principle on 28 January 2020. The protocol, as accepted by the journal, can be found at https://doi.org/10.6084/m9.figshare.12086781.v1 . In this Registered Report, Isler et al. test whether religious cooperation is intuitively parochial. They find evidence of religious parochialism but not intuitive cooperation. Exploratory analyses suggest that deliberation tends to promote cooperation in general.
- Published
- 2021
27. Evolutionary Game and Simulation of Subject Risk Management Behavior in Construction Stage of Engineering Project Based on Strong Reciprocity and Prospect Theory
- Author
-
Dan Wang, Qian Jia, and Ruixue Zhang
- Subjects
General Computer Science ,0211 other engineering and technologies ,Strong reciprocity ,strong reciprocity theory ,02 engineering and technology ,Microeconomics ,Engineering project ,Prospect theory ,021105 building & construction ,0502 economics and business ,General Materials Science ,Risk management ,Government ,evolutionary game ,business.industry ,05 social sciences ,General Engineering ,risk management behavior ,prospect theory ,TK1-9971 ,Risk perception ,Electrical engineering. Electronics. Nuclear engineering ,Evolution strategy ,Construct (philosophy) ,business ,Game theory ,050203 business & management - Abstract
In this study, to reduce the occurrence of risks and risk accidents in the construction stages of engineering projects and strengthen the risk management abilities of the subjects of such projects, prospect theory is introduced into an evolutionary game to construct a risk management behavior game model between owners and contractors in the construction stage. In addition, a government penalty parameter is introduced based on strong reciprocity theory. The intrinsic laws and optimal evolutionary stability strategy in the behavior evolution game between the two parties are analyzed. The influences of different parameter changes on the evolution results are simulated. The study shows that the game model has five local equilibrium points, and that positive risk management for both parties is a stable evolutionary strategy. The factors influencing the evolution results include the cost of positive risk management, risk perception loss and its share ratio, risk perception loss discount coefficient, and negative penalty coefficient. The differences in risk perceptions and effect of prospect theory hinder the behaviors of both parties from evolving towards the optimal strategy. By means of a negative penalty, a strong reciprocal government strategy can effectively coordinate the risk behavior strategies of both parties. Based on the analysis, suggestions are proposed for strengthening the effective management of risks in the construction stages of engineering projects.
- Published
- 2021
28. Strong Reciprocity in Consumer Boycotts.
- Author
-
Hahn, Tobias and Albert, Noël
- Subjects
BOYCOTTS ,RECIPROCITY (Psychology) ,CONSUMER behavior ,MOTIVATION (Psychology) ,CONSUMER psychology - Abstract
Boycotts are among the most frequent forms of consumer expression against unethical or egregious acts by firms. Most current research explains consumers' decisions to participate in a boycott using a universal cost-benefit model that mixes instrumental and expressive motives. To date, no conceptual framework accounts for the distinct behavioral motives for boycotting though. This article focuses on motivational heterogeneity among consumers. By distinguishing two stable behavioral models-a self-regarding type and a strongly reciprocal type-we introduce the notion of strong reciprocity to the boycott literature. We argue that the presence of strongly reciprocal consumers can enhance boycott success. First, in interactions with the target firm, strongly reciprocal consumers perceive higher levels of egregiousness and are more willing to engage in boycotting behavior, even in unfavorable strategic conditions, which provides a stable basis for boycotting. Second, in interactions with self-regarding consumers, strongly reciprocal consumers are willing to sanction those others, according to whether they participate in the boycott, which increases overall participation in and the likelihood of success of a consumer boycott. These findings have implications for further research, as well as for firms, nongovernmental organizations, and boycotters. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2017
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
29. Dashcam Witness: Video Sharing Motives and Privacy Concerns Across Different Nations
- Author
-
Uichin Lee, Joohyun Kim, and Sangkeun Park
- Subjects
Information privacy ,General Computer Science ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Internet privacy ,Dashboard (business) ,Globe ,Strong reciprocity ,privacy concerns ,Perception ,medicine ,General Materials Science ,Electrical and Electronic Engineering ,Reciprocal altruism ,video sharing ,media_common ,business.industry ,General Engineering ,Smart vehicles ,Witness ,user motivation ,medicine.anatomical_structure ,Self-disclosure ,lcsh:Electrical engineering. Electronics. Nuclear engineering ,Business ,autonomous vehicles ,dashcam videos ,lcsh:TK1-9971 - Abstract
Vehicle dashboard cameras or dashcams, among other smart vehicle technologies, are increasingly attracting interest across the globe. Furthermore, dashcam videos as objective witnesses are often shared to resolve various traffic incidents. In this work, we aim to understand cross-national differences in motives and privacy concerns of dashcam video-sharing, which are closely related to the factors that vary across countries, such as cultural values, traffic regulation, driving environments, and privacy perception. Toward this goal, we conduct a cross-national survey study with three countries with high dashcam adoption rates, i.e., China, Korea, and Russia. The survey results from these countries consistently revealed two major motives for sharing dashcam data: (1) reciprocal altruism and social justice, and (2) monetary reward. Respondents from all three countries felt more strongly towards reciprocal altruism and social justice and less towards monetary rewards. Regarding privacy concerns, however, the surveys presented discrepancies among these countries, indicating stronger cross-national influences on sharing concerns than on sharing motives. Cross-national differences in privacy concerns and their relationship with motives were nuanced and context-dependent.
- Published
- 2020
30. Rational altruism? On preference estimation and dictator game experiments
- Author
-
Philip Grech and Heinrich H. Nax
- Subjects
Economics and Econometrics ,media_common.quotation_subject ,05 social sciences ,Rationality ,Strong reciprocity ,Experimental economics ,Altruism ,Charitable giving ,Dictator games ,CES utility functions ,Distributional preferences ,Social preferences ,Foundations ,Dictator game ,0502 economics and business ,Economics ,Dictator ,050206 economic theory ,050207 economics ,Preference (economics) ,Mathematical economics ,Finance ,media_common - Abstract
Experimental implementations of dictator games are found to differ in terms of their underlying strategic incentives. We explore this discovery in two separate directions. Theoretically, assuming identical other-regarding preferences, we show that the two most widely used protocols can generate strongly contrasting rational-choice predictions, from which different interpretations of dictator giving arise. Experimentally, a tailor-made experiment reveals significant differences between the two protocols but rejects full rationality as a satisfactory explanatory theory. Our findings indicate that several previously drawn conclusions regarding other-regarding preferences among humans distinguished by social class, gender, generation, nationality, etc. may be more ambiguous than hitherto believed. ISSN:0899-8256
- Published
- 2020
31. The Image of Humans
- Author
-
Christian A. Conrad
- Subjects
ComputingMilieux_THECOMPUTINGPROFESSION ,Ultimatum game ,Economics ,Strong reciprocity ,Ethical behavior ,Positive economics ,Homo economicus ,Image (mathematics) - Abstract
The following chapter analyzes human behavior in the economy. What motivates people, what goals do they pursue and what makes them happy? We need the insights gained to explain unethical behavior and to move people to ethical behavior.
- Published
- 2022
32. Decoupling cooperation and punishment in humans shows that punishment is not an altruistic trait
- Author
-
Claire Guérin and Maxwell N. Burton-Chellew
- Subjects
General Immunology and Microbiology ,Punishment ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Strong reciprocity ,General Medicine ,Norm enforcement ,Social preferences ,Altruism ,Biological Evolution ,General Biochemistry, Genetics and Molecular Biology ,Microeconomics ,Game Theory ,Public goods game ,Economics ,Trait ,Humans ,Behaviour ,Cooperative Behavior ,General Agricultural and Biological Sciences ,Decoupling (electronics) ,General Environmental Science ,media_common - Abstract
Economic experiments have suggested that cooperative humans will altruistically match local levels of cooperation (conditional cooperation) and pay to punish non-cooperators (altruistic punishment). Evolutionary models have suggested that if altruists punish non-altruists this could favour the evolution of costly helping behaviours (cooperation) among strangers. An often-key requirement is that helping behaviours and punishing behaviours form one single conjoined trait (strong reciprocity). Previous economics experiments have provided support for the hypothesis that punishment and cooperation form one conjoined, altruistically motivated, trait. However, such a conjoined trait may be evolutionarily unstable, and previous experiments have confounded a fear of being punished with being surrounded by cooperators, two factors that could favour cooperation. Here, we experimentally decouple the fear of punishment from a cooperative environment and allow cooperation and punishment behaviour to freely separate (420 participants). We show, that if a minority of individuals is made immune to punishment, they (i) learn to stop cooperating on average despite being surrounded by high levels of cooperation, contradicting the idea of conditional cooperation and (ii) often continue to punish, ‘hypocritically’, showing that cooperation and punishment do not form one, altruistically motivated, linked trait.
- Published
- 2021
33. Why humans might help strangers
- Author
-
Nichola Jayne Raihani and Redouan eBshary
- Subjects
prisoner's dilemma ,strong reciprocity ,Human cooperation ,Cultural group selection ,One-shot games ,error-management ,Neurosciences. Biological psychiatry. Neuropsychiatry ,RC321-571 - Abstract
Humans regularly help strangers, even when interactions are apparently unobserved and unlikely to be repeated. Such situations have been simulated in the laboratory using anonymous one-shot games (e.g. prisoner's dilemma) where the payoff matrices used make helping biologically altruistic. As in real-life, participants often cooperate in the lab in these one-shot games with non-relatives, despite that fact that helping is under negative selection under these circumstances. Two broad explanations for such behavior prevail. The 'big mistake' or 'mismatch' theorists argue that behavior is constrained by psychological mechanisms that evolved predominantly in the context of repeated interactions with known individuals. In contrast, the cultural group selection theorists posit that humans have been selected to cooperate in anonymous one-shot interactions due to strong between-group competition, which creates interdependence among in-group members. We present these two hypotheses before discussing alternative routes by which humans could increase their direct fitness by cooperating with strangers under natural conditions. In doing so, we explain why the standard lab games do not capture real-life in various important aspects. First, asymmetries in the cost of perceptual errors regarding the context of the interaction (one-shot versus repeated; anonymous versus public) might have selected for strategies that minimize the chance of making costly behavioral errors. Second, helping strangers might be a successful strategy for identifying other cooperative individuals in the population, where partner choice can turn strangers into interaction partners. Third, in many real-world situations individuals are able to parcel investments such that a one-shot interaction is turned into a repeated game of many decisions. Finally, in contrast to the assumptions of the prisoner's dilemma model, it is possible that benefits of cooperation follow a non-linear function of investment. Non-li
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
34. Beauty stereotypes in social norm enforcement The effect of attractiveness on third-party punishment and reward.
- Author
-
Putz, Ádám, Palotai, Róbert, Csertő, István, and Bereczkei, Tamás
- Subjects
- *
STEREOTYPES , *SOCIAL norms , *PUNISHMENT , *REWARD (Psychology) , *RECIPROCITY (Psychology) ,ENFORCEMENT - Abstract
The present study analyzes how attractiveness affects social norm enforcement in a context of third-party punishment and reward. The authors developed a Third-Party Punishment and Reward Game (TPRG) that consisted of two steps. First, subjects observed a short Public Goods Game between two fictitious players; afterwards they had the opportunity to punish or reward either one or both players. Interfering in the game was costly for the subjects. The eight rounds of the game comprised scenarios that were either stereotype-consistent (attractive cooperators and unattractive free-riders) or stereotype-inconsistent (attractive free-riders and unattractive cooperators). Subjects' emotional responses to each fictitious player were registered. Participants (N = 197) were found to punish attractive free-riders less severely than unattractive ones, whereas attractive cooperators were rewarded more than unattractive ones. Our present findings may support a so-called "beauty priority": attractiveness was highly valued by participants even among players who cheated. Furthermore, the intensity of subjects' emotional responses reflected the amounts of punishment and reward they allocated to players. The above results led to the conclusion that stereotype-consistent scenarios evoke more extreme emotions and interventions than stereotype-inconsistent ones. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2016
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
35. Investigating the funding success factors affecting reward-based crowdfunding projects
- Author
-
Tser-Yieth Chen, Cheng-Chun Lee, and Tsai-Lien Yeh
- Subjects
Ideal (set theory) ,Management of Technology and Innovation ,Success factors ,Strong reciprocity ,Business ,Marketing - Abstract
The issue of which factors influence the success or failure of crowdfunding projects is a critical topic, as it can bring founders sufficient financial support to realise their ideal innovation. We...
- Published
- 2019
36. Food Sharing and Empathic Emotion Regulation: An Evolutionary Perspective
- Author
-
Thomas R Alley
- Subjects
reciprocal altruism ,strong reciprocity ,food sharing ,empathic emotion regulation ,food transfer ,Psychology ,BF1-990 - Published
- 2014
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
37. HUMAN ALTRUISM AND COOPERATION EXPLAINABLE AS ADAPTATIONS TO PAST ENVIRONMENTS NO LONGER FULLY EVIDENT IN THE MODERN WORLD.
- Author
-
Phillips, Tim and Dykhuizen, Handling Editor Daniel E.
- Subjects
- *
ALTRUISM , *ETHICS , *EVOLUTIONARY psychology , *HUMAN evolution , *SELFISH genetic elements - Abstract
Evolutionary theory predicts rigorous competition in nature and selfish behavior is thus seen as its inevitable consequence. Evidence of altruistic and cooperative behavior therefore appears at odds with evolutionary theory. However, evolutionary psychology suggests that past environments may be different from the current environments that humans inhabit. Here it is hypothesized that competition in two past environments might have led to strategies that favored altruism and cooperation toward nonkin. First, the expansion of the human brain is seen as requiring long-term, quality parental investment to sustain it. Altruistic displays could well have signaled an ability and willingness to provide such parental investment in a potential mate and been favored as a result. Second, the development of extra-somatic weapons is seen as leading to competition within hominin groups becoming more costly as disputes would have become lethal. A cooperative strategy could have achieved greater net fitness if the benefits of reduced involvement in such lethal disputes exceeded the costs of cooperation. Genes associated with human altruism and cooperation toward nonkin could thus have increased in frequency and come to be expressed in modern human populations despite the environments in which they evolved no longer being fully evident in the modern world. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
38. Punish and perish?
- Author
-
Antoci, Angelo and Zarri, Luca
- Subjects
- *
COOPERATION , *SOCIAL sciences , *BEHAVIORAL economics , *RECIPROCITY (Commerce) , *ENDOGENEITY (Econometrics) - Abstract
The evolution of large-scale cooperation among strangers is a fundamental unanswered question in the social sciences. Behavioral economics has persuasively shown that the so-called strong reciprocity plays a key role in accounting for the endogenous enforcement of cooperation. Insofar as strongly reciprocal players are willing to costly sanction defectors, cooperation flourishes. However, experimental evidence unambiguously indicates that not only defection and strong reciprocity, but also unconditional cooperation without punishment is a quantitatively important behavioral attitude. By referring to a prisoner’s dilemma framework where punishment (“stick”) and rewarding (“carrot”) options are available, here we show analytically that the presence of cooperators who don’t punish in the population makes altruistic punishment evolutionarily weak. We show that cooperation breaks down and strong reciprocity is maladaptive if costly punishment means “punishing defectors” and, even more so, if it is coupled with costly rewarding of cooperators. In contrast, punishers do not perish if cooperators, far from being rewarded, are sanctioned. These results, based on an extended notion of strong reciprocity, challenge evolutionary explanations of cooperation that overlook the “dark side” of altruistic behavior. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
39. Why humans might help strangers.
- Author
-
Raihani, Nichola J. and Bshary, Redouan
- Subjects
STRANGERS ,XENOPHOBIA ,ALTRUISM ,HELPING behavior ,INFERENCE (Logic) - Abstract
Humans regularly help strangers, even when interactions are apparently unobserved and unlikely to be repeated. Such situations have been simulated in the laboratory using anonymous one-shot games (e.g., prisoner's dilemma) where the payoff matrices used make helping biologically altruistic. As in real-life, participants often cooperate in the lab in these one-shot games with non-relatives, despite that fact that helping is under negative selection under these circumstances. Two broad explanations for such behavior prevail. The "big mistake" or "mismatch" theorists argue that behavior is constrained by psychological mechanisms that evolved predominantly in the context of repeated interactions with known individuals. In contrast, the cultural group selection theorists posit that humans have been selected to cooperate in anonymous one-shot interactions due to strong between-group competition, which creates interdependence among in-group members. We present these two hypotheses before discussing alternative routes by which humans could increase their direct fitness by cooperating with strangers under natural conditions. In doing so, we explain why the standard lab games do not capture real-life in various important aspects. First, asymmetries in the cost of perceptual errors regarding the context of the interaction (one-shot vs. repeated; anonymous vs. public) might have selected for strategies that minimize the chance of making costly behavioral errors. Second, helping strangers might be a successful strategy for identifying other cooperative individuals in the population, where partner choice can turn strangers into interaction partners. Third, in contrast to the assumptions of the prisoner's dilemma model, it is possible that benefits of cooperation follow a non-linear function of investment. Nonlinear benefits result in negative frequency dependence even in one-shot games. Finally, in many real-world situations individuals are able to parcel investments such that a one-shot interaction is turned into a repeated game of many decisions. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
40. Zašto ljudi sarađuju i kažnjavaju? Logika snažnog reciprociteta.
- Author
-
Dekić, Milovan
- Abstract
Copyright of Yearbook of the Faculty of Political Sciences / Godisnjak Fakultet Politickih Nauka Beograd is the property of University of Belgrade, Faculty of Political Sciences and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use. This abstract may be abridged. No warranty is given about the accuracy of the copy. Users should refer to the original published version of the material for the full abstract. (Copyright applies to all Abstracts.)
- Published
- 2014
41. El pluralismo motivacional en la especie humana. Aportaciones recientes de la ciencia social experimental
- Subjects
Egoísmo ,Reciprocitat forta ,Motivation ,Teoría de la elección racional ,Rational Choice Theory ,Reciprocidad fuerte ,Motivació ,Egoisme ,Teoria de l'elecció racional ,Self-interest ,Motivación ,Strong reciprocity - Published
- 2021
42. Explaining human altruism
- Author
-
Michael Vlerick and Tilburg Center for Logic, Ethics and Philosophy of Science
- Subjects
media_common.quotation_subject ,ENFORCEMENT ,Strong reciprocity ,Kin selection ,Moral reasoning ,Altruism ,Human altruism ,050105 experimental psychology ,CULTURE ,03 medical and health sciences ,0302 clinical medicine ,HUMAN COOPERATION ,SEMANTICS ,0501 psychology and cognitive sciences ,SOCIETIES ,Reciprocal altruism ,Positive economics ,PUNISHMENT ,media_common ,Group selection ,Cultural group selection ,Behavioral game theory ,05 social sciences ,Behavioral game-theory ,General Social Sciences ,Genetic group selection ,STRONG RECIPROCITY ,EVOLUTION ,Philosophy ,Psychology ,030217 neurology & neurosurgery ,BEHAVIOR - Abstract
Humans often behave altruistically towards strangers with no chance of reciprocation. From an evolutionary perspective, this is puzzling. The evolution of altruistic cooperative behavior—in which an organism’s action reduces its fitness and increases the fitness of another organism (e.g. by sharing food)—only makes sense when it is directed at genetically related organisms (kin selection) or when one can expect the favor to be returned (reciprocal altruism). Therefore, evolutionary theorists such as Sober and Wilson have argued that we should revise Neo-Darwininian evolutionary theory. They argue that human altruism evolved through group selection in which groups of altruists were naturally selected because they had a comparative advantage over other groups. Wilson and Sober’s hypothesis attracted followers but is rejected by most of their peers. The heated debate between advocates and critics of group selection often suffers from a lack of conceptual clarity. In response, I set out to clearly distinguish ‘genetic’ from ‘cultural’ group selection (developed by Boyd, Richerson & Henrich) and argue that the latter does not face the potentially debilitating problems plaguing the former. I defend the claim that human altruistic dispositions evolved through cultural group selection and gene-culture coevolution and offer empirical evidence in support. I also argue that actual altruistic behavior often goes beyond the kind of behavior humans have evolved to display. Conscious and voluntary reasoning processes, I show, have an important role in altruistic behavior. This is often overlooked in the scientific literature on human altruism.
- Published
- 2021
43. El pluralismo motivacional en la especie humana. Aportaciones recientes de la ciencia social experimental
- Author
-
Tena Sánchez, Jordi
- Subjects
Egoísmo ,Reciprocitat forta ,Motivation ,Teoría de la elección racional ,Rational Choice Theory ,Reciprocidad fuerte ,Motivació ,Egoisme ,Teoria de l'elecció racional ,Self-interest ,Motivación ,Strong reciprocity - Abstract
Rational Choice Theory has made crucial contributions for the study of social phenomena. However, the utilization of false or too simple assumptions supposes an important limitation in this sense. This paper begins with a refusal of the common adoption of a motivationally monist point of view in which self-interest is the only motivation capable of explaining social action. In this paper, first, I offer a general overview of the most important kinds of human motivation identified by the specialized literature. Then, I focus on the quantitatively most important one: strong reciprocity. The paper finishes with a discussion about the possibility of incorporating plural motivations in formal models., La teoría de la elección racional ha realizado aportaciones decisivas para el estudio de los fenómenos sociales. No obstante, el uso de supuestos falsos o excesivamente incompletos supone un importante lastre en este sentido. El presente trabajo parte del rechazo a la adopción rutinaria de un punto de vista monista motivacional, según el cual el egoísmo es el único tipo de supuesto motivacional capaz de dar cuenta de la acción social. En estas páginas se trata, primero, de esbozar una panorámica general de los tipos de motivación humana más importantes identificados por la bibliografía especializada, para, posteriormente, centrarse específicamente en el cuantitativamente más importante de todos ellos, la reciprocidad fuerte. El trabajo concluye con una discusión sobre la posibilidad de incluir una pluralidad de motivaciones en los modelos formales.
- Published
- 2021
44. Altruistic Punishment and Strong Reciprocity
- Author
-
Tünde Paál
- Subjects
Punishment ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Strong reciprocity ,Psychology ,Social psychology ,media_common - Published
- 2021
45. Intuitive decision-making promotes rewarding prosocial others independent of the personality trait Honesty-Humility
- Author
-
Laila, Nockur and Stefan, Pfattheicher
- Subjects
Adult ,Male ,Decision Making ,Emotions ,lcsh:Medicine ,Trust ,Article ,Reward ,ACCOUNT ,Human behaviour ,Humans ,Psychology ,PUNISHMENT ,lcsh:Science ,COOPERATION ,SOCIAL HEURISTICS ,lcsh:R ,STRONG RECIPROCITY ,Altruism ,EVOLUTION ,TIME ,Female ,lcsh:Q ,AGREEABLENESS ,TRUST ,BEHAVIOR ,Personality - Abstract
Although past research has convincingly shown that rewarding prosocial individuals helps to establish high levels of cooperation, research investigating factors that promote rewarding others has been surprisingly rare. The present research addresses this gap and examines two factors that were shown in past research to play a role in prosocial behaviour. In a well-powered study (total N = 1003), we tested the impact of (a) a basic prosocial personality trait (the Honesty-Humility dimension from the HEXACO personality model) and (b) intuitive decision-making, as well as (c) their interaction, in rewarding prosocial individuals. We found that (1) intuition promotes rewarding prosocial others; (2) Honesty-Humility was not significantly related to rewarding prosocial others; and (3) that Honesty-Humility did not significantly moderate the effect of intuition on reward. Implications for the understanding of reciprocating others’ prosocial behaviour are discussed.
- Published
- 2020
46. The Necessity for Strong Reciprocators in Mobile Ad Hoc Networks.
- Author
-
Seredynski, Marcin, Danoy, Gregoire, and Bouvry, Pascal
- Abstract
In civilian mobile ad hoc networks behaviour of network participants in accordance with the collective interest cannot be guaranteed. The cooperation in packet forwarding can emerge if the reciprocal tit-for-tat (TFT) principle is commonly used. This induces the nodes with self-regarding preferences to act cooperatively. However, as demonstrated in this paper, in certain conditions costs of using a reciprocal forwarding are greater than benefits. In such a case, the cooperation can emerge only if nodes with specific behaviour called strong reciprocity are present in the network. This paper analyses such conditions using a nature-inspired evolutionary approach. The computational experiments demonstrate that as soon as at least approximately 70% of nodes follow the TFT-principle in packet forwarding, benefits of its use exceed costs, regardless the forwarding behaviour of the remaining nodes. Consequently, strong reciprocators are not required for sustaining cooperative network. Below that threshold, the need for strong reciprocators depends on the composition of the remaining nodes. In particular, it is positively correlated with the number of unconditionally cooperative nodes as these nodes create incentives for free-riding behaviour. [ABSTRACT FROM PUBLISHER]
- Published
- 2012
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
47. Human-robot cooperation in economic games: People show strong reciprocity but conditional prosociality toward robots
- Author
-
Chaudhury B, Te-Yi Hsieh, and Cross Es
- Subjects
Dilemma ,Incentive ,Profit (accounting) ,Reciprocity (social psychology) ,Robot ,Strong reciprocity ,Situational ethics ,Psychology ,Social psychology ,Human–robot interaction - Abstract
Understanding the social dynamics in human-robot cooperation stands to broaden our understanding of human behaviour in general, as well as to improve the design of robots designated for certain social tasks. This study investigated human cooperative behaviours in the context of prisoner’s dilemma (PD) games and the extent to which people’s willingness to cooperate with a robot varies according to incentives provided by the game context. We manipulated the payoff matrices of human-robot PD games and predicted that people would cooperate more often in the situation where cooperating with the robot was a relatively more rewarding option. Although the pre-registered mixed effect logistic regression model showed no significant effect of incentive structure on human decisions in the iterated PD games overall, further exploratory analyses revealed that in early game rounds, participants made significantly more cooperative decisions when the game structure provided more incentives for cooperation. However, subsequent game decisions were dominantly driven by other two factors. The first was the robot’s previous game choices, where participants played a tit-for-tat strategy against the robot even though its decisions were random. Second, presentation of real-time game scores significantly impacted people’s cooperative tendencies. Participants only showed prosocial tendencies toward the robot when they had achieved high scores themselves. Our findings on the initial effects of incentive structure, robust reciprocity, and conditional prosociality in human-robot cooperation highlight ways in which we might expect social behaviour toward robots to differ from social behaviour toward humans, and help to establish the foundations necessary to support successful social collaboration with robots.
- Published
- 2020
48. The rise and fall of cooperation in populations with multiple groups
- Author
-
Xianjia Wang, Jinhua Zhao, Rui Ding, and Cuiling Gu
- Subjects
Microeconomics ,Computational Mathematics ,education.field_of_study ,genetic structures ,Applied Mathematics ,Mutation (genetic algorithm) ,Population ,Public goods game ,Economics ,Moran process ,Strong reciprocity ,education ,Human society - Abstract
It is a challenge to understand why cooperation is prevalent in human society, especially without a mechanism that benefits cooperators such as direct, indirect and strong reciprocity. We study an evolutionary process of public goods game among individuals in multiple groups in a population. We find that the existence of an independent cooperator group is beneficial to the rise of cooperation in the population, which is applicable to both Moran process and a so-called disaster update process proposed in this paper. However, the introduction of mutation can completely overturn the emerging trend of cooperation, and even let the defectors occupy the whole population for a short period of time, by continuously reducing the number of cooperator groups. In addition, the migration of individuals between groups can also inhibit cooperation. More specifically, a higher frequency of migration can reduce the probability of cooperators occupying the population, and extend the time it takes for the population to reach the stationary state. Furthermore, we find that a special kind of multi-individual migration, namely group division, can resist the anti-cooperation effect of mutation to some extent, mainly by maintaining a certain number of cooperator groups in the population. The aforementioned results suggest that cooperation can rise without strengthening the ability of cooperators to directly confront the defectors in a population composed of multiple groups.
- Published
- 2022
49. Dynamics and orientation selectivity in a cortical model of rodent V1 with excess bidirectional connections
- Author
-
Pattadkal, Jagruti, Mato, Germán, Van Vreeswijk, Carl, Priebe, Nicholas, Hansel, David, Departamento de Fisica Teorica, Universidad Autonoma de Madrid (UAM), Neurophysique et physiologie du système moteur (NPSM), Université Paris Descartes - Paris 5 (UPD5)-Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique (CNRS), and Centre de neurophysique, physiologie, pathologie (UMR 8119)
- Subjects
0301 basic medicine ,Fano factor ,Population ,Action Potentials ,lcsh:Medicine ,Rodentia ,Strong reciprocity ,Inhibitory postsynaptic potential ,Article ,03 medical and health sciences ,0302 clinical medicine ,Animals ,education ,lcsh:Science ,ComputingMilieux_MISCELLANEOUS ,Cerebral Cortex ,Neurons ,[PHYS]Physics [physics] ,education.field_of_study ,Multidisciplinary ,Chemistry ,Dynamics (mechanics) ,lcsh:R ,Cortex (botany) ,030104 developmental biology ,Reciprocity (network science) ,Excitatory postsynaptic potential ,lcsh:Q ,[SDV.NEU]Life Sciences [q-bio]/Neurons and Cognition [q-bio.NC] ,Neuroscience ,030217 neurology & neurosurgery - Abstract
Recent experiments have revealed fine structure in cortical microcircuitry. In particular, bidirectional connections are more prevalent than expected by chance. Whether this fine structure affects cortical dynamics and function has not yet been studied. Here we investigate the effects of excess bidirectionality in a strongly recurrent network model of rodent V1. We show that reciprocal connections have only a very weak effect on orientation selectivity. We find that excess reciprocity between inhibitory neurons slows down the dynamics and strongly increases the Fano factor, while for reciprocal connections between excitatory and inhibitory neurons it has the opposite effect. In contrast, excess bidirectionality within the excitatory population has a minor effect on the neuronal dynamics. These results can be explained by an effective delayed neuronal self-coupling which stems from the fine structure. Our work suggests that excess bidirectionality between inhibitory neurons decreases the efficiency of feature encoding in cortex by reducing the signal to noise ratio. On the other hand it implies that the experimentally observed strong reciprocity between excitatory and inhibitory neurons improves the feature encoding.
- Published
- 2019
50. Heterogeneous game resource distributions promote cooperation in spatial prisoner’s dilemma game
- Author
-
Sheng-Wen Tian, Jun Yue, Yan-Cun Yang, Guanghai Cui, and Zhen Wang
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Non-cooperative game ,Computer science ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Normal-form game ,Screening game ,Strong reciprocity ,Prisoner's dilemma ,Temptation ,Condensed Matter Physics ,01 natural sciences ,010305 fluids & plasmas ,Microeconomics ,Dilemma ,Win-win game ,Resource (project management) ,0103 physical sciences ,010306 general physics ,media_common - Abstract
In social networks, individual abilities to establish interactions are always heterogeneous and independent of the number of topological neighbors. We here study the influence of heterogeneous distributions of abilities on the evolution of individual cooperation in the spatial prisoner’s dilemma game. First, we introduced a prisoner’s dilemma game, taking into account individual heterogeneous abilities to establish games, which are determined by the owned game resources. Second, we studied three types of game resource distributions that follow the power-law property. Simulation results show that the heterogeneous distribution of individual game resources can promote cooperation effectively, and the heterogeneous level of resource distributions has a positive influence on the maintenance of cooperation. Extensive analysis shows that cooperators with large resource capacities can foster cooperator clusters around themselves. Furthermore, when the temptation to defect is high, cooperator clusters in which the central pure cooperators have larger game resource capacities are more stable than other cooperator clusters.
- Published
- 2018
Catalog
Discovery Service for Jio Institute Digital Library
For full access to our library's resources, please sign in.