33 results on '"Johan Tysk"'
Search Results
2. Space-time adaptive finite difference method for European multi-asset options.
- Author
-
Per Lötstedt, Jonas Persson, Lina von Sydow, and Johan Tysk
- Published
- 2007
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
3. Feynman–Kac theorems for generalized diffusions
- Author
-
Erik Ekström, Johan Tysk, and Svante Janson
- Subjects
Discrete mathematics ,Pure mathematics ,symbols.namesake ,Applied Mathematics ,General Mathematics ,Representation (systemics) ,symbols ,Feynman diagram ,Uniqueness ,Type (model theory) ,Mathematics - Abstract
We find Feynman–Kac type representation theorems for generalized diffusions. To do this we need to establish existence, uniqueness and regularity results for equations with measure-valued coefficients.
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
4. Comparison of Two Methods for Superreplication
- Author
-
Erik Ekström and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Pointwise ,Covariance matrix ,Quadratic form ,Applied Mathematics ,Mathematical analysis ,Regular polygon ,Portfolio ,Parabolic partial differential equation ,Value (mathematics) ,Finance ,Convexity ,Mathematics - Abstract
We compare two methods for superreplication of options with convex pay-off functions. One method entails the overestimation of an unknown covariance matrix in the sense of quadratic forms. With this method the value of the superreplicating portfolio is given as the solution of a linear Black–Scholes BS-type equation. In the second method, the choice of quadratic form is made pointwise. This leads to a fully non-linear equation, the so-called Black–Scholes–Barenblatt (BSB) equation, for the value of the superreplicating portfolio. In general, this value is smaller for the second method than for the first method. We derive estimates for the difference between the initial values of the superreplicating strategies obtained using the two methods.
- Published
- 2012
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
5. Can time-homogeneous diffusions produce any distribution?
- Author
-
David Hobson, Erik Ekström, Svante Janson, and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Pure mathematics ,Homogeneous ,Mathematical finance ,Probability (math.PR) ,FOS: Mathematics ,Calculus ,Statistics, Probability and Uncertainty ,Martingale (probability theory) ,Mathematics - Probability ,Analysis ,Mathematics - Abstract
Given a centred distribution, can one find a time-homogeneous martingale diffusion starting at zero which has the given law at time 1? We answer the question affirmatively if generalized diffusions are allowed.
- Published
- 2011
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
6. Numerical option pricing in the presence of bubbles
- Author
-
Erik Ekström, Lina von Sydow, Johan Tysk, and Per Lötstedt
- Subjects
Valuation of options ,Monte Carlo methods for option pricing ,Local martingale ,Economics ,Computational mathematics ,Arbitrage ,Finite difference methods for option pricing ,Implied volatility ,General Economics, Econometrics and Finance ,Mathematical economics ,Measure (mathematics) ,Finance - Abstract
Standard arbitrage theory shows that the absence of arbitrage is equivalent to the existence of an equivalent local martingale measure. In most models used for option pricing, including, for exampl...
- Published
- 2011
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
7. The Black–Scholes equation in stochastic volatility models
- Author
-
Erik Ekström and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Boundary conditions ,Stochastic volatility ,Option pricing ,Parabolic equations ,Applied Mathematics ,Mathematical analysis ,Mixed boundary condition ,Parabolic partial differential equation ,Uniqueness theorem for Poisson's equation ,Free boundary problem ,Cauchy boundary condition ,Uniqueness ,Boundary value problem ,Feynman–Kac theorems ,Analysis ,Mathematics - Abstract
We study the Black–Scholes equation in stochastic volatility models. In particular, we show that the option price is the unique classical solution to a parabolic differential equation with a certain boundary behaviour for vanishing values of the volatility. If the boundary is attainable, then this boundary behaviour serves as a boundary condition and guarantees uniqueness in appropriate function spaces. On the other hand, if the boundary is non-attainable, then the boundary behaviour is not needed to guarantee uniqueness, but is nevertheless very useful for instance from a numerical perspective.
- Published
- 2010
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
8. Optimal liquidation of a call spread
- Author
-
Johan Tysk, Henrik Wanntorp, Carl Lindberg, and Erik Ekström
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Mathematical optimization ,Probability theory ,General Mathematics ,Optimal stopping ,Model parameters ,Sensitivity (control systems) ,Volatility (finance) ,Implied volatility ,Statistics, Probability and Uncertainty ,Mathematical economics ,Mathematics - Abstract
We study the optimal liquidation strategy for a call spread in the case when an investor, who does not hedge, believes in a volatility that differs from the implied volatility. The liquidation problem is formulated as an optimal stopping problem, which we solve explicitly. We also provide a sensitivity analysis with respect to the model parameters.
- Published
- 2010
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
9. Boundary Values and Finite Difference Methods for the Single Factor Term Structure Equation
- Author
-
Johan Tysk, Erik Ekström, and Per Lötstedt
- Subjects
Matrix difference equation ,Partial differential equation ,Applied Mathematics ,Mathematical analysis ,Structure equation ,Finite difference method ,Computational mathematics ,Finite difference coefficient ,Finance ,Poincaré–Steklov operator ,Term (time) ,Mathematics - Abstract
Boundary values and finite difference methods for the single factor term structure equation
- Published
- 2009
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
10. Convexity preserving jump-diffusion models for option pricing
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Erik Ekström
- Subjects
Large class ,Integro-differential equations ,35B99 ,Option price orderings ,Options ,Jump diffusion ,Monotonic function ,Convexity ,FOS: Economics and business ,Mathematics - Analysis of PDEs ,Jump-diffusions ,FOS: Mathematics ,91B28 ,60J75 ,Mathematics ,Applied Mathematics ,Probability (math.PR) ,Valuation of options ,Jump ,Pricing of Securities (q-fin.PR) ,Volatility (finance) ,Quantitative Finance - Pricing of Securities ,Mathematical economics ,Mathematics - Probability ,Analysis ,Analysis of PDEs (math.AP) - Abstract
We investigate which jump-diffusion models are convexity preserving. The study of convexity preserving models is motivated by monotonicity results for such models in the volatility and in the jump parameters. We give a necessary condition for convexity to be preserved in several-dimensional jump-diffusion models. This necessary condition is then used to show that, within a large class of possible models, the only convexity preserving models are the ones with linear coefficients., Comment: 14 pages
- Published
- 2007
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
11. FEYNMAN–KAC FORMULAS FOR BLACK–SCHOLES-TYPE OPERATORS
- Author
-
Svante Janson and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Geometric Brownian motion ,Partial differential equation ,General Mathematics ,Converse theorem ,Mathematical analysis ,Converse ,Zero (complex analysis) ,Boundary (topology) ,Applied mathematics ,Boundary value problem ,Constant (mathematics) ,Mathematics - Abstract
There are many references showing that a classical solution to the Black-Scholes equation is a stochastic solution. However, it is the converse of this theorem which is most relevant in applications and the converse is also more mathematically interesting. In the present article we establish such a converse. We find a Feynman-Kac type theorem showing that the stochastic representation yields a classical solution to the corresponding Black-Scholes equation with appropriate boundary conditions under very general conditions on the coefficients. We also obtain additional regularity results in the one-dimensional case. Stochastic formulas for option prices are often easy to formulate and to implement in for instance Monte Carlo algorithms. It is natural from the point of view of applications to let zero be an absorbing barrier for processes describing the risky assets. In Section 3 we discuss such a representation in the case of time- and level-dependent volatilities. However, it is often advantageous to instead solve the corresponding Black-Scholes equation and thus be able to use results from the theory of partial differential equations. In the literature one often omits specifying the boundary conditions on the lateral part of the parabolic boundary. This causes no problem when the risky assets are modelled with geometric Brownian motion, since assets in this model reach zero with probability zero. However, for many models, such as the constant elasticity of variance models, the values of the assets can vanish with positive probability and boundary conditions need to be specified. Furthermore, in numerical applications one is often helped by knowing the boundary behavior of the solution even if these conditions are mathematically redundant to specify. In fact, there are many references showing that a classical solution to the Black-Scholes equation is a stochastic solution, compare Theorem 2.5. How- ever, it is the converse of this theorem which is most relevant in applications as described above and the converse is also more mathematically subtle. In the present article we establish such a converse. We find a a Feynman-Kac type theorem showing that the stochastic representation yields a classical so- lution to the corresponding Black-Scholes equation with appropriate bound- ary conditions, compare Theorem 5.5. We also obtain additional regularity results in the one-dimensional case.
- Published
- 2006
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
12. The American put is log-concave in the log-price
- Author
-
Erik Ekström and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,Actuarial science ,Cost price ,Concave function ,Applied Mathematics ,Statistics::Other Statistics ,Put–call parity ,Elasticity ,Econometrics ,Asian option ,Log-concavity ,Elasticity (economics) ,Put option ,Moneyness ,American options ,Stock (geology) ,Analysis ,Mathematics - Abstract
We show that the American put option price is log-concave as a function of the log-price of the underlying asset. Thus the elasticity of the price decreases with increasing stock value. We also consider related contracts of American type, and we provide an example showing that not all American option prices are log-concave in the stock log-price.
- Published
- 2006
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
13. A boundary point lemma for Black-Scholes type operators
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Erik Ekström
- Subjects
Lemma (mathematics) ,35K65 ,35B50 ,Applied Mathematics ,Mathematical analysis ,Boundary (topology) ,General Medicine ,Black–Scholes model ,Céa's lemma ,Parabolic partial differential equation ,FOS: Economics and business ,Mathematics - Analysis of PDEs ,FOS: Mathematics ,Hopf lemma ,Pricing of Securities (q-fin.PR) ,Quantitative Finance - Pricing of Securities ,Analysis ,Analysis of PDEs (math.AP) ,Mathematics - Abstract
We prove a sharp version of the Hopf boundary point lemma for Black-Scholes type equations. We also investigate the existence and the regularity of the spatial derivative of the solutions at the spatial boundary., 10 pages
- Published
- 2006
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
14. OPTIONS WRITTEN ON STOCKS WITH KNOWN DIVIDENDS
- Author
-
Erik Ekström and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Financial economics ,Volatility smile ,Economics ,Non-qualified stock option ,Asian option ,Black–Scholes model ,Implied volatility ,Put–call parity ,General Economics, Econometrics and Finance ,Moneyness ,Strike price ,Finance - Abstract
There are two common methods for pricing European call options on a stock with known dividends. The market practice is to use the Black–Scholes formula with the stock price reduced by the present value of the dividends. An alternative approach is to increase the strike price with the dividends compounded to expiry at the risk-free rate. These methods correspond to different stock price models and thus in general give different option prices. In the present paper we generalize these methods to time- and level-dependent volatilities and to arbitrary contract functions. We show, for convex contract functions and under very general conditions on the volatility, that the method which is market practice gives the lower option price. For call options and some other common contracts we find bounds for the difference between the two prices in the case of constant volatility.
- Published
- 2004
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
15. Preservation of convexity of solutions to parabolic equations
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Svante Janson
- Subjects
Parabolic equation ,Spatial variable ,Applied Mathematics ,Mathematical analysis ,Regular polygon ,Parabolic partial differential equation ,Convexity ,Logarithmically convex function ,Convex optimization ,Initial value problem ,Convex function ,Analysis ,Mathematics - Abstract
In the present paper we find necessary and sufficient conditions on the coefficients of a parabolic equation for convexity to be preserved. A parabolic equation is said to preserve convexity if given a convex initial condition, any solution of moderate growth remains a convex function of the spatial variables for each fixed time.
- Published
- 2004
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
16. Boundary conditions for the single-factor term structure equation
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Erik Ekström
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Bond option ,Differential equation ,stochastic representation ,Probability (math.PR) ,Mathematical analysis ,Boundary (topology) ,35K65 ,35A05 ,Term (time) ,91B28 ,Perspective (geometry) ,Short rate ,FOS: Mathematics ,degenerate parabolic equations ,Uniqueness ,Boundary value problem ,Statistics, Probability and Uncertainty ,The term structure equation ,Mathematics - Probability ,Mathematics ,60J60 - Abstract
We study the term structure equation for single-factor models that predict nonnegative short rates. In particular, we show that the price of a bond or a bond option is the unique classical solution to a parabolic differential equation with a certain boundary behavior for vanishing values of the short rate. If the boundary is attainable then this boundary behavior serves as a boundary condition and guarantees uniqueness of solutions. On the other hand, if the boundary is nonattainable then the boundary behavior is not needed to guarantee uniqueness but it is nevertheless very useful, for instance, from a numerical perspective., Comment: Published in at http://dx.doi.org/10.1214/10-AAP698 the Annals of Applied Probability (http://www.imstat.org/aap/) by the Institute of Mathematical Statistics (http://www.imstat.org)
- Published
- 2011
17. Optimal Liquidation of a Pairs Trade
- Author
-
Erik Ekström, Carl Lindberg, and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Financial economics ,business.industry ,Econometrics ,Economics ,Pairs trade ,Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process ,Model parameters ,Optimal stopping ,business ,Profit (economics) ,Hedge fund - Abstract
Pairs trading is a common strategy used by hedge funds. When the spread between two highly correlated assets is observed to deviate from historical observations, a long position is taken in the underpriced asset, and a short position in the overpriced one. If the spread narrows, both positions are closed, thus generating a profit. We study when to optimally liquidate a pairs trading strategy when the difference between the two assets is modeled by an Ornstein–Uhlenbeck process. We also provide a sensitivity analysis in the model parameters.
- Published
- 2011
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
18. Behavior of the poincaré metric near a fractal boundary
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Sidney Frankel
- Subjects
symbols.namesake ,Bounded function ,Mathematical analysis ,Metric (mathematics) ,Poincaré metric ,Minkowski distance ,Minkowski–Bouligand dimension ,symbols ,General Medicine ,Curvature ,Chebyshev distance ,Intrinsic metric ,Mathematics - Abstract
Given a simply connected domain ω in the complex plane with boundary of Minkowski dimension α, we show that the area with respect to the Poincare metric divided by the area with respect to the quasihyperbolic metric of the super level sets of the distance function to ∂ω is asymptotically bounded by α2 as the distance decreases to zero. These bounds are established using a symmetrization argument, showing that the Poincare area of a subdomain of ω can be estimated in terms of a conformal modulus of its complement. We find a generalization of this result to locally simply connected domains and also show that the curvature of the quasi-hyperbolic metric tends to -α on the average, as we approach ∂ω. This behavior of the curvature leads us to conjecture that the bound α2 can be replaced by α.
- Published
- 1993
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
19. Eigenvalue estimates and isoperimetric inequalities for cone-manifolds
- Author
-
Craig D. Hodgson and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Pure mathematics ,General Mathematics ,Mathematical analysis ,Isoperimetric dimension ,Mathematics::Geometric Topology ,Cone (topology) ,Bounded function ,Gravitational singularity ,Mathematics::Differential Geometry ,Isoperimetric inequality ,Mathematics::Symplectic Geometry ,Laplace operator ,Eigenvalues and eigenvectors ,Ricci curvature ,Mathematics - Abstract
This paper studies eigenvalue bounds and isoperimetric inequalities for Rieman-nian spaces with cone type singularities along a codimension-2 subcomplex. These “cone-manifolds” include orientable orbifolds, and singular geometric structures on 3-manifolds studied by W. Thurston and others.We first give a precise definition of “cone-manifold” and prove some basic results on the geometry of these spaces. We then generalise results of S.-Y. Cheng on upper bounds of eigenvalues of the Laplacian for disks in manifolds with Ricci curvature bounded from below to cone-manifolds, and characterise the case of equality in these estimates.We also establish a version of the Lévy-Gromov isoperimetric inequality for cone-manifolds. This is used to find lower bounds for eigenvalues of domains in cone-manifolds and to establish the Lichnerowicz inequality for cone-manifolds. These results enable us to characterise cone-manifolds with Ricci curvature bounded from below of maximal diameter.
- Published
- 1993
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
20. Eigenvalue problems for manifolds with singularities
- Author
-
Johan Tysk
- Published
- 1993
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
21. Bubbles, convexity and the Black–Scholes equation
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Erik Ekström
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,Parabolic equations ,stochastic representation ,Probability (math.PR) ,35K65 ,Black–Scholes model ,Measure (mathematics) ,local martingales ,Convexity ,91B28 ,Valuation of options ,Bounded function ,preservation of convexity ,FOS: Mathematics ,Local martingale ,35K65, 60G44 (Primary) 60G40, 91B28 (Secondary) ,60G44 ,Uniqueness ,Statistics, Probability and Uncertainty ,Volatility (finance) ,Mathematical economics ,60G40 ,Mathematics - Probability ,Mathematics - Abstract
A bubble is characterized by the presence of an underlying asset whose discounted price process is a strict local martingale under the pricing measure. In such markets, many standard results from option pricing theory do not hold, and in this paper we address some of these issues. In particular, we derive existence and uniqueness results for the Black--Scholes equation, and we provide convexity theory for option pricing and derive related ordering results with respect to volatility. We show that American options are convexity preserving, whereas European options preserve concavity for general payoffs and convexity only for bounded contracts., Comment: Published in at http://dx.doi.org/10.1214/08-AAP579 the Annals of Applied Probability (http://www.imstat.org/aap/) by the Institute of Mathematical Statistics (http://www.imstat.org)
- Published
- 2009
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
22. Convexity theory for the term structure equation
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Erik Ekström
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Mathematical optimization ,Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,35B99 ,Logarithm ,Computational Finance (q-fin.CP) ,Monotonic function ,Convexity ,FOS: Economics and business ,Mathematics - Analysis of PDEs ,Quantitative Finance - Computational Finance ,FOS: Mathematics ,91B28 ,Economics ,Applied mathematics ,Bond convexity ,Mathematical finance ,Probability (math.PR) ,Bond valuation ,Short rate ,Statistics, Probability and Uncertainty ,Volatility (finance) ,Finance ,Mathematics - Probability ,Analysis of PDEs (math.AP) - Abstract
We study the convexity and model parameter monotonicity properties for prices of bonds and bond options when the short rate is modeled by a diffusion process. We provide sharp conditions on the model parameters under which the convexity of the price in the short rate is guaranteed. Under these conditions, the price is decreasing in the drift and increasing in the volatility of the short rate. We also study the convexity properties of the logarithm of the price and find simple conditions on the coefficients that guarantee that the price is log-convex or log-concave.
- Published
- 2007
23. Properties of option prices in models with jumps
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Erik Ekström
- Subjects
Economics and Econometrics ,Statistical Finance (q-fin.ST) ,35B99 ,Applied Mathematics ,Regular polygon ,Quantitative Finance - Statistical Finance ,Monotonic function ,Stock price ,Convexity ,Option value ,91B28 ,FOS: Economics and business ,Mathematics - Analysis of PDEs ,60J75 ,Accounting ,Economics ,Jump ,FOS: Mathematics ,Volatility (finance) ,Martingale (probability theory) ,Mathematical economics ,Social Sciences (miscellaneous) ,Finance ,Analysis of PDEs (math.AP) - Abstract
We study convexity and monotonicity properties of option prices in a model with jumps using the fact that these prices satisfy certain parabolic integro-differential equations. Conditions are provided under which preservation of convexity holds, i.e. under which the value, calculated under a chosen martingale measure, of an option with a convex contract function is convex as a function of the underlying stock price. The preservation of convexity is then used to derive monotonicity properties of the option value with respect to the different parameters of the model, such as the volatility, the jump size and the jump intensity., 14 pages
- Published
- 2005
24. Volatility time and properties of option prices
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Svante Janson
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Stochastic volatility ,convexity ,time decay ,stochastic time ,Implied volatility ,SABR volatility model ,Convexity ,91B28 ,contingent claim ,Stochastic differential equation ,35K15 ,Stopping time ,Volatility ,Volatility smile ,Statistics, Probability and Uncertainty ,Volatility (finance) ,60H30 ,Mathematical economics ,Mathematics - Abstract
We use a notion of stochastic time, here called volatility time, to show convexity of option prices in the underlying asset if the contract function is convex as well as continuity and monotonicity of the option price in the volatility. The volatility time is obtained as the almost surely unique stopping time solution to a random ordinary differential equation related to volatility. This enables us to write price processes, or processes modeled by local martingales, as Brownian motions with respect to volatility time. The results are shown under very weak assumptions and are of independent interest in the study of stochastic differential equations. Options on several underlying assets are also studied and we prove that if the volatility matrix is independent of time, then the option prices decay with time if the contract function is convex. However, the option prices are no longer necessarily convex in the underlying assets and the option prices do not necessarily decay with time, if a time-dependent volatility is allowed.
- Published
- 2003
25. PRICING EQUATIONS IN JUMP-TO-DEFAULT MODELS
- Author
-
Johan Tysk, Erik Ekström, and Hannah Dyrssen
- Subjects
Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,Jump-to-default model, credit risk, martingales, the Black–Scholes equation ,Boundary (topology) ,Monotonic function ,Convexity ,Connection (mathematics) ,Economics ,Jump ,Boundary value problem ,Focus (optics) ,General Economics, Econometrics and Finance ,Mathematical economics ,Finance ,Credit risk - Abstract
We study pricing equations in jump-to-default models, and we provide conditions under which the option price is the unique classical solution, with a special focus on boundary conditions. In particular, we find precise conditions ensuring that the option price at the default boundary coincides with the recovery payment. We also study spatial convexity of the option price, and we explore the connection between preservation of convexity and parameter monotonicity.
- Published
- 2014
26. Upper Bounds for the Poincaré Metric Near a Fractal Boundary
- Author
-
Sidney Frankel and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
symbols.namesake ,Bounded function ,Metric (mathematics) ,Poincaré metric ,Mathematical analysis ,symbols ,Minkowski–Bouligand dimension ,Symmetrization ,Boundary (topology) ,Complex plane ,Unit disk ,Mathematics - Abstract
Given a simply connected domain Ω in the complex plane with boundary of Minkowski dimension α, we show that the area with respect to the Poincare metric divided by the area with respect to the quasi-hyperbolic metric of the super level sets of the distance function to ∂Ω is asymptotically bounded by α2 as the distance decreases to zero. Provided that the distance function has no local maximum points arbitrarily close to the boundary, we improve this estimate to α. These bounds are established using a symmetrization argument, showing that the Poincare area of a subdomain of Ω can be estimated in terms of a conformal modulus of its complement. This modulus is then estimated using test functions constructed from the lengths of the level curves of the distance function. We find a generalization of these results to locally simply connected domains and also show that the curvature of the quasi-hyperbolic metric tends to —α on the average, as we approach ∂Ω.
- Published
- 1997
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
27. DUPIRE'S EQUATION FOR BUBBLES
- Author
-
Erik Ekström and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,Dupire's equation, strict local martingales, financial bubbles ,Local volatility ,Economics ,Local martingale ,Option price ,Uniqueness ,Martingale (probability theory) ,General Economics, Econometrics and Finance ,Mathematical economics ,Finance ,Economic bubble - Abstract
We study Dupire's equation for local volatility models with bubbles, i.e. for models in which the discounted underlying asset follows a strict local martingale. If option prices are given by risk-neutral valuation, then the discounted option price process is a true martingale, and we show that the Dupire equation for call options contains extra terms compared to the usual equation. However, the Dupire equation for put options takes the usual form. Moreover, uniqueness of solutions to the Dupire equation is lost in general, and we show how to single out the option price among all possible solutions. The Dupire equation for models in which the discounted derivative price process is merely a local martingale is also studied.
- Published
- 2012
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
28. Schrödinger Operators and Index Bounds for Minimal Submanifolds
- Author
-
Johan Tysk and Shiu-Yuen Cheng
- Subjects
symbols.namesake ,Pure mathematics ,Index (economics) ,General Mathematics ,symbols ,Mathematical economics ,Eigenvalues and eigenvectors ,Schrödinger's cat ,Mathematics - Published
- 1994
29. Comparison of two methods of multiplying distributions
- Author
-
Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Discrete mathematics ,Sequence ,Discrete Fourier transform (general) ,Distribution (mathematics) ,Applied Mathematics ,General Mathematics ,Product (mathematics) ,Mathematical analysis ,Convolution theorem ,Convolution ,Fourier transform on finite groups ,Sequence transformation ,Mathematics - Abstract
There is no canonical way of defining a product of distributions. In the present paper we compare two different methods of defining a product of distributions. These methods are based on the sequential and functional-analytic approaches to distributions. Introduction. In many applications of distribution theory a product of distributions occurs. There is, however, no canonical way to define such a product. In this article we shall discuss two different methods of defining a product of two distributions. The sequential approach leads to one way of defining a product, and, using Fourier analysis, we obtain a second product based on the functional-analytic definition of distributions. We call this product the product in the Fourier sense; it is essentially defined as in [1]. We shall compare the two definitions and prove that if that product exists in the Fourier sense, it also exists in the sequential sense, and the products are equal. This article is based on an undergraduate thesis published at the Department of Mathematics at Uppsala University in September 1981. Professor Christer 0. Kiselman gave me invaluable help both with my undergraduate thesis and the present paper. I take this opportunity to thank him. The sequential method. First let us study a product based on the sequential approach. To do this we will need so-called 8-sequences: Let an, n > 1, be positive real numbers such that an--* 0 as n xo. Let dn E C0&(B(0, an)) where B(O, an) {X E Rm: lxl < an}. Assume that
- Published
- 1985
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
30. Finiteness of index and total scalar curvature for minimal hypersurfaces
- Author
-
Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Hypersurface ,Mean curvature ,Euclidean space ,Applied Mathematics ,General Mathematics ,Bounded function ,Second fundamental form ,Prescribed scalar curvature problem ,Mathematical analysis ,Curvature ,Mathematics ,Scalar curvature - Abstract
Let M n , n ≥ 3 {M^n},n \geq 3 , be an oriented minimally immersed complete hypersurface in Euclidean space. We show that for n = 3 , 4 , 5 , or 6 n = 3,4,5,{\text { or }}6 , the index of M n {M^n} is finite if and only if the total scalar curvature of M n {M^n} is finite, provided that the volume growth of M n {M^n} is bounded by a constant times r n {r^n} , where r r is the Euclidean distance function. We also note that this result does not hold for n ≥ 8 n \geq 8 . Moreover, we show that the index of M n {M^n} is bounded by a constant multiple of the total scalar curvature for all n ≥ 3 n \geq 3 , without any assumptions on the volume growth of M n {M^n} .
- Published
- 1989
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
31. An index characterization of the catenoid and index bounds for minimal surfaces in R4
- Author
-
Shiu-Yuen Cheng and Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Minimal surface ,Index (economics) ,Catenoid ,General Mathematics ,Mathematical analysis ,Characterization (mathematics) ,Mathematics - Published
- 1988
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
32. Space–time adaptive finite difference method for European multi-asset options
- Author
-
Lina von Sydow, Jonas Persson, Johan Tysk, and Per Lötstedt
- Subjects
Discretization ,Basket option ,Monte Carlo method ,Mathematical analysis ,Finite difference method ,Time adaptation ,Parabolic partial differential equation ,Space adaptation ,Regular grid ,Computational Mathematics ,Maximum principle ,Black–Scholes equation ,Computational Theory and Mathematics ,Adjoint equation ,Modeling and Simulation ,Modelling and Simulation ,Mathematics - Abstract
The multi-dimensional Black–Scholes equation is solved numerically for a European call basket option using a priori–a posteriori error estimates. The equation is discretized by a finite difference method on a Cartesian grid. The grid is adjusted dynamically in space and time to satisfy a bound on the global error. The discretization errors in each time step are estimated and weighted by the solution of the adjoint problem. Bounds on the local errors and the adjoint solution are obtained by the maximum principle for parabolic equations. Comparisons are made with Monte Carlo and quasi-Monte Carlo methods in one dimension, and the performance of the method is illustrated by examples in one, two, and three dimensions.
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
33. Eigenvalue estimates with applications to minimal surfaces
- Author
-
Johan Tysk
- Subjects
Combinatorics ,Minimal surface ,General Mathematics ,58G11 ,Geometry ,53C42 ,58G25 ,Eigenvalues and eigenvectors ,Mathematics ,35P15 - Abstract
On etudie des estimations de valeur propre des recouvrements de Riemann ramifies des varietes compactes. On demontre que si φ:M n →N n est un recouvrement de Riemann ramifie, et {μ i } i=0 ∞ et {λ i } i=0 ∞ sont les valeurs propres de l'operateur de Laplace-Beltrami sur M et N, alors Σ i=0 ∞ exp(-μit)≤kΣ i=0 ∞ exp(−λit) pour tout t positif, ou k est le nombre de couches du recouvrement
- Published
- 1987
Catalog
Discovery Service for Jio Institute Digital Library
For full access to our library's resources, please sign in.