The article by Peter Huckfeldt and colleagues (Huckfeldt et al. 2013) in this issue of Health Services Research focuses on the market impact of several payment changes instituted between 1997 and 2010 by the Medicare program for postacute care services, including skilled nursing care, home health care and rehabilitation services. Several of these reforms changed reimbursement from its historical cost basis to a prospective payment model, similar to the Diagnostic Related Group system implemented in 1983 and used by Medicare to reimburse inpatient care provided by hospitals. Other payment changes included moving from cost-based reimbursement to per diem or per discharge payments, with all models focused on setting “appropriate” payment rates as a function of expected resource needs based on scientific evidence and clinical guidelines, adjusting for patients' clinical severity and functional ability to account for the fact that patients require different levels of services depending on their clinical and functional status. As Huckfeldt et al. (2013) describe, these payment changes can be viewed as affecting both the average payment per service and the marginal payment for a service, with the goal of these changes being to reduce unnecessary or excessive utilization, and to create incentives for health care providers to organize and deliver services more efficiently, at least within the limits of the new reimbursement levels. The Huckfeldt et al. (2013) article uses retrospective analysis of Medicare data to ask an important question—what impact did these payment changes have on the concentration of providers in the postacute care market? Specifically, did the payment changes result in increased provider entry or exit? Did the payment changes result in consolidation or regionalization of services or vertical integration across the continuum of postacute care? The authors' motivate their empirical work by developing hypotheses from a conceptual framework with its roots in prior work by Bresnahan and Reiss (1994). The Bresnahan and Reiss model, which has been used by other health economists, is rooted in microeconomic theories of the firm and of production, modeling health care providers' entry, exit, and scale/scope decisions as a function of cost structure (fixed, variable, and sunk costs for entrants), demand, and the revenue expected per unit of service provided. Depending on the mix of payment changes (e.g., changes in marginal or average payments), the model yields either certain or ambiguous hypotheses regarding provider entry, exit and scope/scale, but nevertheless, the authors estimate the relationship empirically using historical data before and after these various payment changes took effect. To confirm that changes in entry, exit, and provider concentration were due to Medicare's payment changes, as opposed to some other temporal trend, the authors investigate the presence of larger effects in markets with a higher percentage of care paid for by Medicare, also known as the Medicare share. So what did the authors find? Not surprisingly, they found that the level and composition of reimbursement mattered and that estimated changes were largely consistent with the hypotheses generated by their conceptual model. Specifically, the authors found that when payment policies reduced both average and marginal payments, new provider entries decreased while provider exits increased, consistent with theoretical predictions. When payment policies resulted in reduced marginal payments with increased average payments, as was the case with the home health and inpatient rehabilitation services prospective payment systems, the results were mixed, consistent with ambiguous predictions from the conceptual model. For example, for home health care, entrants increased while the number of exiting firms decreased, with no statistically significant relationship estimated for inpatient rehabilitation services. In addition, the authors estimated greater changes in entry and exit in markets where Medicare held a greater share of the overall reimbursement, suggesting that the changes were due to payment policies rather than temporal trends. A central question not answered by the authors' analysis, however, is whether these payment reforms resulted in the socially optimal number and concentration of providers. This is a key question, as reducing the number of entrants or even prompting competitors to exit the marketplace may be viewed as positive in an excess supply scenario, particularly if those leaving (or not entering) the market are less efficient than those that remain. On the other hand, a reduction in competitors or provider capacity may be negative in a shortage situation that results in clinically harmful delays in accessing appropriate care. But what is the socially optimal quantity and concentration of providers? That answer is not as simple as one might think, but certainly involves considering (a) the “ideal” number of providers needed to provide a reasonable level of access to care for a relevant geographic or patient population; (b) the reasonable preferences of patients regarding location, diversity, and practice style; and (c) the economically efficient organization and delivery of care, where efficiency considers both economies of scale (a positive) and excessive market power (a negative). The answer should also consider the production possibility frontier, and the possibility that, in some instances, certain types of providers might be capable of substituting for other types of providers, thus making both reductions and additions in the capacity of particular provider types desirable.