16 results on '"Edward R. Morrison"'
Search Results
2. Bargaining around Bankruptcy: Small Business Workouts and State Law
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
Bankruptcy ,Federal rules of bankruptcy procedure (United States. Supreme Court) ,Finance ,Actuarial science ,Creditor ,business.industry ,Restructuring ,State law ,FOS: Law ,Federal aid to small business ,Debtor ,Small business ,Federal law ,Rest (finance) ,Economics ,Default ,business ,Law ,Senior debt - Abstract
In the United States, few failing businesses invoke the Bankruptcy Code to reorganize or liquidate. Most use non-bankruptcy procedures to accomplish the same purposes. These procedures include voluntary agreements between the debtor and its creditors (workouts) and formal devices such as friendly foreclosures, bulk sales, and assignments for the benefit of creditors. This paper documents the importance of non-bankruptcy procedures using firm-level data from Cook County, Illinois. I find that these procedures are used by eighty percent of distressed small businesses. The paper also identifies the conditions under which a business chooses federal bankruptcy law over non-bankruptcy procedures. I model this choice - theoretically and empirically - as the outcome of a bargaining game between the debtor's owner and its senior lenders. The parties are more likely to consent to non-bankruptcy procedures when bargaining costs are low and when the debtor has maintained a close relationship with senior lenders, who trust the information provided by the owner. When the number of senior lenders is relatively large (raising bargaining costs) or when the debtor has defaulted on senior debt (thereby harming its relationship with lenders), senior lenders are more likely to push for a federal bankruptcy filing. Owners may also prefer a federal filing when in-bankruptcy rules give greater priority to particular creditors whom the owner would like to favor. These findings suggest that federal bankruptcy reforms, such as the Bankruptcy Abuse and Protection Act of 2005, will have two effects on distressed small businesses: They will impact outcomes in federal courts (intensive margin) as well as the debtor's choice between bankruptcy and non-bankruptcy procedures (extensive margin). Variation along the extensive margin can neutralize reforms in federal law, as when a reform designed to protect unsecured creditors raises the cost of federal law and induces businesses to use cheaper non-bankruptcy procedures instead.
- Published
- 2009
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
3. Rules of Thumb for Intercreditor Agreements
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
restrict ,Collateral ,Creditor ,Bankruptcy ,Cash ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Voting ,Law ,Economics ,Lien ,Rule of thumb ,media_common - Abstract
Intercreditor agreements frequently restrict the extent to which subordinated creditors can participate in the bankruptcy process by, for example, contesting liens of senior lenders, objecting to a cash collateral motion, or even exercising the right to vote on a plan of reorganization. Because intercreditor agreements can reorder the bargaining environment in bankruptcy, some judges have been unsure about their enforceability. Other judges have not hesitated to enforce the agreements, at least when they do not restrict the voting rights of subordinated creditors. This essay argues that intercreditor agreements are controversial because they pose a trade-off: they reduce bargaining costs (by limiting the participatory rights of subordinated creditors), but can give senior lenders outsized influence over the bankruptcy process, to the detriment of investors who were not party to the intercreditor agreement. The essay proposes several rules of thumb that might help judges navigate this trade-off.
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
4. Bankruptcy Decision Making
- Author
-
Douglas G. Baird and Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
Finance ,Organizational Behavior and Human Resource Management ,Economics and Econometrics ,business.industry ,Shutdown ,Control (management) ,Discount points ,Microeconomics ,Incentive ,Bankruptcy ,Value (economics) ,Economics ,Common value auction ,business ,Law ,Shut down - Abstract
When a firm encounters financial distress, there is a significant possibility that, at some point, the firm itself should be shut down and its assets put to better use. But Chapter 11 and indeed all market-mimicking reorganization regimes other than a speedy auction entrust the shutdown decision to a bankruptcy judge who lacks information and expertise, as well as the ability to control the timing of her decisions. Understanding the costs of entrusting the shutdown decision to a bankruptcy judge is central to assessing any law of corporate reorganizations. This article models the shutdown decision as the exercise of a real option. The model suggests that the shutdown decision may loom so large in the early parts of the bankruptcy case that it erases any significant difference between Chapter 11 and many alternative market-mimicking regimes. All these regimes take more time than mandatory auctions and thus increase the cost of taking the shutdown decision away from a market actor. Moreover, the real option itself gives parties an incentive to withhold information. Only a system of mandatory auctions both limits the amount of time the shutdown option resides with an inexpert decision maker and forces insiders to give that decision maker sufficient information to value the option
- Published
- 2001
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
5. Coasean Bargaining in Consumer Bankruptcy
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
Microeconomics ,Gains from trade ,Coase theorem ,Bankruptcy ,Property rights ,Tautology (rhetoric) ,Economics ,Outcome (game theory) - Abstract
During my first weeks as a graduate student in economics, a professor described the Coase Theorem as “nearly a tautology:” Assume a world in which bargaining is costless. If there are gains from trade, the Theorem tells us, the parties will trade. The initial assignment of property rights will not affect the final allocation because the parties will bargain (costlessly) to an efficient outcome. “How can that be a theorem?,” I remember thinking at the time.
- Published
- 2014
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
6. Mortgage Modification and Strategic Behavior: Evidence from a Legal Settlement with Countrywide
- Author
-
Arpit Gupta, Edward R. Morrison, Christopher J. Mayer, and Tomasz Piskorski
- Subjects
Economics and Econometrics ,Exploit ,State government ,Monetary economics ,Mortgage modification ,jel:D10 ,Corporation ,jel:G21 ,jel:D14 ,jel:G33 ,jel:K0 ,jel:K22 ,jel:R31 ,Economics ,Strategic behavior ,Juvenile delinquency ,Default ,Settlement (litigation) - Abstract
We investigate whether homeowners respond strategically to news of mortgage modification programs. We exploit plausibly exogenous variation in modification policy induced by U.S. state government lawsuits against Countrywide Financial Corporation, which agreed to offer modifications to seriously delinquent borrowers with subprime mortgages throughout the country. Using a difference-in-difference framework, we find that Countrywide's relative delinquency rate increased thirteen percent per month immediately after the program's announcement. The borrowers whose estimated default rates increased the most in response to the program were those who appear to have been the least likely to default otherwise, including those with substantial liquidity available through credit cards and relatively low combined loan-to-value ratios. These results suggest that strategic behavior should be an important consideration in designing mortgage modification programs.
- Published
- 2011
7. Mortgage Modification and Strategic Behavior: Evidence from a Legal Settlement with Countrywide
- Author
-
Christopher J. Mayer, Tomasz Piskorski, Edward R. Morrison, and Arpit Gupta
- Subjects
Finance ,business.industry ,Settlement (finance) ,Juvenile delinquency ,Economics ,Financial system ,Default ,Mortgage modification ,Mortgage insurance ,Shared appreciation mortgage ,business ,Corporation ,Market liquidity - Abstract
We investigate whether homeowners respond strategically to news of mortgage modification programs by defaulting on their mortgages. We exploit plausibly exogenous variation in modification policy induced by U.S. state government lawsuits against Countrywide Financial Corporation, which agreed to offer modifications to seriously delinquent borrowers with mortgages throughout the country. Using a difference-in-difference framework, we find that Countrywide's relative delinquency rate increased more than ten percent per month immediately after the program's announcement. The borrowers whose estimated default rates increased the most in response to the program were those who appear to have been the least likely to default otherwise, including those with substantial liquidity available through credit cards and relatively low combined loan-to-value ratios. These results suggest that strategic behavior of borrowers should be an important consideration in designing mortgage modification programs.
- Published
- 2011
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
8. Dodd-Frank for Bankruptcy Lawyers
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison and Douglas G. Baird
- Subjects
Constitutionality ,Bankruptcy ,Law ,Market stability ,Economics ,Bank regulation ,Legislation ,Policy objectives ,Code (semiotics) - Abstract
The Dodd-Frank financial reform legislation creates an “Orderly Liquidation Authority” (OLA) that shares many features in common with the Bankruptcy Code. This is easy to overlook because the legislation uses a language and employs a decision-maker (both borrowed from bank regulation) that will seem foreign to bankruptcy lawyers. Our task in this essay is to identify the core congruities between OLA and the Code. In doing so, we highlight important differences and assess both their constitutionality and policy objectives. We conclude with a few thoughts on the likelihood that OLA will contribute to market stability.
- Published
- 2011
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
9. Chrysler, GM and the Future of Chapter 11
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
Government ,General motors ,Economy ,Bankruptcy ,Restructuring ,Creditor ,Economic interventionism ,Control (management) ,Economics ,Financial system ,Treasury - Abstract
Although they caused great controversy, the Chrysler and GM bankruptcies broke no new ground. They invoked procedures that are commonly observed in modern Chapter 11 reorganization cases. Government involvement did not distort the bankruptcy process; it instead exposed the reality that Chapter 11 offers secured creditors - especially those that supply financing during the bankruptcy case - control over the fate of distressed firms. Because the federal government supplied financing in the Chrysler and GM cases, it possessed the creditor control normally exercised by private lenders. The Treasury Department found itself with virtually the same, unchecked power that the FDIC exercises with respect to failing banks. The Chrysler and GM bankruptcies are cautionary tales about Chapter 11, not about government intervention. It may be time to entertain longstanding proposals for reforming the reorganization process.
- Published
- 2009
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
10. The Economics of Bankruptcy: An Introduction to the Literature
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
Corporate finance ,Empirical research ,Work (electrical) ,Restructuring ,Bankruptcy ,Field (Bourdieu) ,Economics ,Positive economics ,Scholarly work ,Management - Abstract
This essay surveys important contributions to the economics of bankruptcy. It is an introductory chapter for a forthcoming volume (from Edward Elgar Press) that compiles the work of legal scholars as well as economists working in the field of corporate finance. The essay begins with the foundational theories of Baird, Jackson, and Rea and then collects scholarly work extending, testing, or revising those theories. At various points I identify questions that merit further study, particularly empirical testing.
- Published
- 2009
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
11. Creditor Control and Conflict in Chapter 11
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison and Kenneth Ayotte
- Subjects
Finance ,Leverage (finance) ,Restructuring ,business.industry ,Creditor ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Control (management) ,Equity (finance) ,Accounting ,Leverage (negotiation) ,Bankruptcy ,Debt ,Economics ,business ,Inefficiency ,Law ,media_common - Abstract
We analyze a sample of large privately and publicly held businesses that filed Chapter 11 bankruptcy petitions during 2001. We find pervasive creditor control. In contrast to traditional views of Chapter 11, equity holders and managers exercise little or no leverage during the reorganization process. 70 percent of CEOs are replaced in the two years before a bankruptcy filing, and few reorganization plans (at most 12 percent) deviate from the absolute priority rule to distribute value to equity holders. Senior lenders exercise significant control through stringent covenants, such as line-item budgets, in loans extended to firms in bankruptcy. Unsecured creditors gain leverage through objections and other court motions. We also find that bargaining between secured and unsecured creditors can distort the reorganization process. A Chapter 11 case is significantly more likely to result in a sale if secured lenders are oversecured, consistent with a secured creditor-driven fire-sale bias. A sale is much less likely when these lenders are undersecured or when the firm has no secured debt at all. Our results suggest that the advent of creditor control has not eliminated the fundamental inefficiency of the bankruptcy process: resource allocation questions (whether to sell or reorganize a firm) are ultimately confounded with distributional questions (how much each creditor will receive) due to conflict among creditor classes.
- Published
- 2008
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
12. Financial Contracts and the New Bankruptcy Code: Insulating Markets from Bankrupt Debtors and Bankruptcy Judges
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison and Joerg Riegel
- Subjects
Finance ,Substance over form ,Swap (finance) ,Bankruptcy ,business.industry ,Financial transaction ,Financial market ,Economics ,Financial system ,Counterparty ,Debtor ,business ,Database transaction - Abstract
The reforms of 2005 yield important but subtle changes in the Bankruptcy Code's treatment of financial contracts. They might appear only to eliminate longstanding uncertainty surrounding the protections available to financial contract counterparties, especially counterparties to repurchase transactions and other derivative contracts. But the ambit of the reforms is much broader. The expanded definitions - especially the definition of "swap agreement" - are now so broad that nearly every derivative contract is subject to the Code's protection. Instead of protecting particular counterparties to particular transactions, the Code now protects any counterparty to any derivative contract. Entire markets have been insulated from the costs of a bankruptcy filing by a financial contract counterparty. Equally important, the amendments limit judicial discretion to assess the economic substance of financial transactions, even those that resemble ordinary loans or that retire a debtor's outstanding debt or equity. The reforms of 2005 direct judges to apply a formalistic inquiry based on industry custom: a financial transaction is a "swap," "repurchase transaction," or other protected transaction if it is treated as such in the relevant financial market. The transaction's loan-like features or its effect on outstanding obligations of the debtor are irrelevant, unless they affect the transaction's characterization in financial markets. Absent fraud, form trumps substance - a desirable outcome, we argue, in light of the impossibility of drawing coherent lines between combinations of ordinary financial contracts and loans, dividends, or debt repurchases.
- Published
- 2006
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
13. Serial Entrepreneurs and Small Business Bankruptcies
- Author
-
Douglas G. Baird and Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
Bankruptcy ,Federal rules of bankruptcy procedure (United States. Supreme Court) ,Finance ,Entrepreneurship ,Guard (information security) ,Actuarial science ,ComputingMilieux_THECOMPUTINGPROFESSION ,business.industry ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Liquidation ,FOS: Law ,Small business ,Human capital ,Asset specificity ,Scarcity ,Empirical research ,Debtor and creditor ,Economics ,Small business--Law and legislation ,business ,Law ,media_common - Abstract
Chapter 11 is thought to preserve the going-concern surplus of a financially distressed business-the extra value that its assets possess in their current configuration. Financial distress leads to conflicts among creditors that can lead to inefficient liquidation of a business with going-concern surplus. Chapter 11 avoids this by providing the business with a way of fashioning a new capital structure. This account of Chapter 11 fails to capture what is happening in the typical case. The typical Chapter 11 debtor is a small corporation whose assets are not specialized and rarely worth enough to pay tax claims. There is no business worth saving and there are no assets to fight over. The focal point is not the business, but the person who runs it. She is a serial entrepreneur, searching for the business that best matches her skills. For the vast majority of cases, then, Chapter 11 is best seen through the lens of labor economics not corporate finance. Chapter 11 offers the entrepreneur increased liquidity as well as a forum for renegotiating debts (such as unpaid withholding taxes) for which she as well as the corporation are liable. But Chapter 11 offers these benefits only to entrepreneurs who remain with their existing businesses. This lock-in effect is qualitatively no different from the one commonly associated with rent control. These effects, as well as the costs the process imposes on third parties, should be the focus of any assessment of how well Chapter 11 works.
- Published
- 2005
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
14. Derivatives and the Bankruptcy Code: Why the Special Treatment?
- Author
-
Franklin R. Edwards and Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
Finance ,Bankruptcy ,business.industry ,Systemic risk ,Derivatives market ,Economics ,Counterparty ,Automatic stay ,Debtor ,business ,Financial market participants ,Bailout - Abstract
The collapse of Long Term Capital Management (LTCM) in Fall 1998 and the Federal Reserve Bank's subsequent efforts to orchestrate a bailout raise important questions about the structure of the Bankruptcy Code. The Code contains numerous provisions affording special treatment to financial derivatives contracts, the most important of which exempts these contracts from the "automatic stay" and permits counterparties to terminate derivatives contracts with a debtor in bankruptcy and seize underlying collateral. No other counterparty or creditor of the debtor has such freedom; to the contrary, the automatic stay prohibits them from undertaking any act that threatens the debtor's assets. It is commonly believed that the exemption for derivatives contracts helps reduce "systemic risk" in financial markets, that is, the risk that multiple major financial market participants will fail at the same time and, as a result, drastically reduce market liquidity. Indeed, Congress is now contemplating reforms that would extend the exemption to include a broader array of financial contracts, all in the name of reducing systemic risk. This is a mistake. The Bankruptcy Code can do little to reduce systemic risk and may in fact exacerbate it, as the experience of LTCM suggests. Risk of a systemic meltdown arose there and prompted intervention by the Fed precisely because derivatives contracts were exempt from the automatic stay. Derivatives contracts may merit special treatment, but fear of systemic risk is a red herring. A better, efficiency-based reason for treating derivatives contracts differently arises naturally from the economic theory underlying the automatic stay. The stay protects assets to the extent they are needed to preserve a firm's going-concern surplus (its value above and beyond the sale value of its assets). Assets are needed to preserve going-concern surplus only if they are firm-specific, that is, only if they are worth more inside the firm than outside it. This is often true for plant and equipment. It is never true for derivatives contracts. This observation helps rationalize the Code's treatment of derivatives contracts and other features of the automatic stay. There are, however, downsides to treating derivatives contracts differently (creditors, for example, would like to disguise loans as derivatives contracts). These downsides are probably not significant, but they highlight the fragility of the Code's treatment of derivatives contracts, which should worry members of Congress as they consider arguments to expand the Code's exemptions for derivatives contracts.
- Published
- 2004
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
15. Bankruptcy Decision-Making: An Empirical Study of Small-Business Bankruptcies
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison
- Subjects
Continuation ,Actuarial science ,Empirical research ,Insolvency ,Restructuring ,business.industry ,Bankruptcy ,Economics ,Conventional wisdom ,Small business ,business ,Hazard - Abstract
Over half of all small businesses reorganizing under Chapter 11 of the U.S. Bankruptcy Code are ultimately liquidated. Little is known about this shutdown decision and about the factors that increase or reduce the amount of time a firm spends in bankruptcy. It is widely suspected, however, that the Chapter 11 process exhibits a "continuation bias," allowing non-viable firms to linger under the protection of the court. This paper tests for the presence of continuation bias in the docket of a typical bankruptcy court over the course of a calendar year. A variety of tests are employed, including the extent to which entrenched managers dominate the bankruptcy process, the accuracy and speed with which viable and nonviable firms are distinguished, and the extent to which the hazard of shutdown is consistent with the implications of a simple, formal model of the optimal Chapter 11 process. Contrary to conventional wisdom, the paper finds that continuation bias is either absent or empirically unimportant.
- Published
- 2003
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
16. Optimal Timing and Legal Decisionmaking: The Case of the Liquidation Decision in Bankruptcy
- Author
-
Edward R. Morrison and Douglas G. Baird
- Subjects
Incentive ,Actuarial science ,Earnings ,Bankruptcy ,Control (management) ,Economics ,Going concern ,Summary judgment ,Liquidation value ,Optimal decision - Abstract
Until the firm is sold or a plan of reorganization is confirmed, Chapter 11 entrusts a judge with the decision of whether to keep a firm as a going concern or to shut it down. The judge revisits this liquidation decision multiple times. The key is to make the correct decision at the optimal time. This paper models this decision as the exercise of a real option and shows that it depends critically on particular types of information about the firm and its industry. Liquidations take place too soon if we merely compare the liquidation value of the assets with the expected earnings of the firm. Moreover, existing law undermines effective decisionmaking. Even though the judge makes the liquidation decision, a number of rules prevent the judge from controlling the timing of the decision, and those who do control it lack the incentive to ensure it is made at the optimal time. The paper introduces a framework that can illuminate many areas of law, such as summary judgment motions, parole, and agency rule making.
- Published
- 1999
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
Catalog
Discovery Service for Jio Institute Digital Library
For full access to our library's resources, please sign in.