99 results on '"Banzhaf power index"'
Search Results
2. THE POWER OF SMALL EU MEMBER STATES AFTER BREXIT: HOW POWERFUL IS THE VISEGRAD GROUP?
- Author
-
Tomas Kajanek
- Subjects
European Union ,Visegrad Group ,Power Index ,Banzhaf Power Index ,Council of the EU ,Small EU Member States ,Political theory ,JC11-607 ,Law - Abstract
The power of individual EU Member States has been changing over the past decades as a result of revisions to the voting systems and the enlargements of the European Union. The present article analyses the development of the voting power of individual Member States in the Council of the European Union before and after the withdrawal of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland from the European Union. We use the calculation of the standardized Banzhaf power index to calculate the legislative power of the Member States. The calculations recorded in the table point to changes in the weights of national votes caused by Brexit. The article pays special attention to the Visegrad Group, which we define within the European Union as an informal group consisting of four Central European states - the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and the Slovak Republic. The results indicate a significant growth of the voting power in Poland and more moderate growth in the other three Visegrad Group countries which contributes to the shift in the voting equilibrium within the ordinary legislative procedure of the European Union.
- Published
- 2022
3. THE POWER OF SMALL EU MEMBER STATES AFTER BREXIT: HOW POWERFUL IS THE VISEGRAD GROUP?
- Author
-
Kajánek, Tomáš
- Subjects
BREXIT Referendum, 2016 ,EUROPEAN Union membership ,PARLIAMENTARY practice ,LEGISLATIVE power ,BRITISH withdrawal from the European Union, 2016-2020 - Abstract
The power of individual EU Member States has been changing over the past decades as a result of revisions to the voting systems and the enlargements of the European Union. The present article analyses the development of the voting power of individual Member States in the Council of the European Union before and after the withdrawal of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland from the European Union. We use the calculation of the standardized Banzhaf power index to calculate the legislative power of the Member States. The calculations recorded in the table point to changes in the weights of national votes caused by Brexit. The article pays special attention to the Visegrad Group, which we define within the European Union as an informal group consisting of four Central European states - the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and the Slovak Republic. The results indicate a significant growth of the voting power in Poland and more moderate growth in the other three Visegrad Group countries which contributes to the shift in the voting equilibrium within the ordinary legislative procedure of the European Union. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2022
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
4. An approach via generating functions to compute power indices of multiple weighted voting games with incompatible players.
- Author
-
Francisco Neto, Antônio and Fonseca, Carolina Rodrigues
- Subjects
- *
GENERATING functions , *COMMUTATIVE algebra , *QUOTIENT rings , *POLYNOMIAL rings , *COMBINATORICS - Abstract
We introduce a new generating function based method to compute the Banzhaf, Deegan–Packel, Public Good (a.k.a. the Holler power index) and Shapley–Shubik power indices in the presence of incompatibility among players. More precisely, given a graph G = V , E with V the set of players and E the edge set, our extension involves multiple weighted voting games (MWVG's) and incompatible players, i.e., pairs of players belonging to E are not allowed to cooperate. The route to obtain the aforementioned generating functions comprises the use of a key lemma characterizing the set of minimal winning coalitions of the game with incompatibility due to Alonso-Meijide et al. (Appl Math Comput 252(1):377–387, 2015), a tool from combinatorial analysis, namely, the Omega calculus in partition analysis, and basic tools borrowed from commutative algebra involving the computation of certain quotients of polynomial rings module polynomial ideals. Using partition analysis, we obtain new generating functions to compute the Deegan–Packel and Public Good power indices with incompatibility leading to lower time complexity than previous results of Chessa (TOP 22(2):658–673, 2014) and some results of Alonso-Meijide et al. (Appl Math Comput 219(8):3395–3402, 2012). Using a conjunction of partition analysis and commutative algebra, we extend to MWVG's the generating function approach to compute the Banzhaf and Shapley–Shubik power indices in the presence of incompatibility. Finally, an example taken from the real-world, i.e., the European Union under the Lisbon Treaty, is used to illustrate the usefulness of the Omega package, a symbolic computational package that implements the Omega calculus in Mathematica, due to Andrews et al. (Eur J Comb 22(7):887–904, 2001) in the context of MWVG's by computing the PG power index of the associated voting game. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2019
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
5. Generating Functions of Weighted Voting Games, MacMahon's Partition Analysis, and Clifford Algebras.
- Author
-
Neto, Antônio Francisco
- Subjects
GENERATING functions ,CLIFFORD algebras ,COMBINATORIAL optimization ,MATHEMATICAL symmetry ,DISTRIBUTION (Probability theory) - Abstract
MacMahon's Partition Analysis (MPA) is a combinatorial tool used in partition analysis to describe the solutions of a linear diophantine system. We show that MPA is useful in the context of weighted voting games. We introduce a new generalized generating function that gives, as special cases, extensions of the generating functions of the Banzhaf, Shapley-Shubik, Banzhaf-Owen, symmetric coalitional Banzhaf, and Owen power indices. Our extensions involve any coalition formation related to a linear diophantine system and multiple voting games. In addition, we show that a combination of ideas from MPA and Clifford algebras is useful in constructing generating functions for coalition configuration power indices. Finally, a brief account on how to design voting systems via MPA is advanced. More precisely, we obtain new generating functions that give, for fixed coalitions, all the distribution of weights of the players of the voting game such that a given player swings or not. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2019
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
6. Cooperative Profit Random Forests With Application in Ocean Front Recognition
- Author
-
Jianyuan Sun, Guoqiang Zhong, Junyu Dong, Hina Saeeda, and Qin Zhang
- Subjects
Random Forests ,cooperative game theory ,Banzhaf power index ,Electrical engineering. Electronics. Nuclear engineering ,TK1-9971 - Abstract
Random Forests are powerful classification and regression tools that are commonly applied in machine learning and image processing. In the majority of random classification forests algorithms, the Gini index and the information gain ratio are commonly used for node splitting. However, these two kinds of node-split methods may pay less attention to the intrinsic structure of the attribute variables and fail to find attributes with strong discriminate ability as a group yet weak as individuals. In this paper, we propose an innovative method for splitting the tree nodes based on the cooperative game theory, from which some attributes with good discriminate ability as a group can be learned. This new random forests algorithm is called Cooperative Profit Random Forests (CPRF). Experimental comparisons with several other existing random classification forests algorithms are carried out on several real-world data sets, including remote sensing images. The results show that CPRF outperforms other existing Random Forests algorithms in most cases. In particular, CPRF achieves promising results in ocean front recognition.
- Published
- 2017
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
7. Extending multidimensional poverty identification: from additive weights to minimal bundles
- Author
-
Sam Jones
- Subjects
Organizational Behavior and Human Resource Management ,Class (set theory) ,Mathematical optimization ,Sociology and Political Science ,Banzhaf power index ,050204 development studies ,05 social sciences ,Function (mathematics) ,Type (model theory) ,Set (abstract data type) ,Identification (information) ,Dimension (vector space) ,0502 economics and business ,Metric (mathematics) ,050207 economics ,General Economics, Econometrics and Finance - Abstract
In the popular class of multidimensional poverty measures introduced by Alkire and Foster (2011), a threshold switching function is used to identify who is multidimensionally poor. This paper shows that the weights and cut-off employed in this procedure are generally not unique and that such functions implicitly assume all groups of deprivation indicators of some fixed size are perfect substitutes. To address these limitations, I show how the identification procedure can be extended to incorporate any type of positive switching function, represented by the set of minimal deprivation bundles that define a unit as poor. Furthermore, the Banzhaf power index, uniquely defined from the same set of minimal bundles, constitutes a natural and robust metric of the relative importance of each indicator, from which the adjusted headcount can be estimated. I demonstrate the merit of this approach using data from Mozambique, including a decomposition of the adjusted headcount using a ‘one from each dimension’ non-threshold function.
- Published
- 2021
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
8. An efficient ensemble pruning approach based on simple coalitional games.
- Author
-
Ykhlef, Hadjer and Bouchaffra, Djamel
- Subjects
- *
STATISTICAL ensembles , *LYMPHANGIOGRAPHY , *PAIRED comparisons (Mathematics) , *AUDIOLOGY , *LOGISTIC regression analysis - Abstract
We propose a novel ensemble pruning methodology using non-monotone Simple Coalitional Games, termed SCG-Pruning. Our main contribution is two-fold: (1) Evaluate the diversity contribution of a classifier based on Banzhaf power index. (2) Define the pruned ensemble as the minimal winning coalition made of the members that together exhibit moderate diversity. We also provide a new formulation of Banzhaf power index for the proposed game using weighted voting games. To demonstrate the validity and the effectiveness of the proposed methodology, we performed extensive statistical comparisons with several ensemble pruning techniques based on 58 UCI benchmark datasets. The results indicate that SCG-Pruning outperforms both the original ensemble and some major state-of-the-art selection approaches. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2017
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
9. Farklı Koalisyon Senaryolarına Bağlı Olarak Türkiye’nin Üyeliği Sonrası Avrupa Birliği’nde Oylama Gücü Dağılımı(Depending On Different Coalition Scenarios Voting Power Distribution In The European Union After Turkey’s Membership)
- Author
-
Hatice Burcu ESKİCİ and Özgür YENİAY
- Subjects
Avrupa Birliği ,Türkiye ,Lizbon Antlaşması ,Banzhaf güç indeksi ,Oylama gücü ,European Union ,Turkey ,Treaty of Lisbon ,Banzhaf power index ,Voting power ,Management. Industrial management ,HD28-70 ,Economics as a science ,HB71-74 - Abstract
It is taken into consideration of the influence on voting power distribution of candidate countries’ European Union membership enlargement is one of the most important issue the for European Union. In this study, the impact of Turkey’s membership on voting power distribution is evaluated for coalition formation determined with hierarchical clustering methods, according to the acts adopted by the Council of the European Union and voting system brought by the Treaty of Lisbon. In the analysis, the effect of Turkey’s membership on voting power distribution is evaluated for four coalition formation determined with hierarchical clustering methods and Banzhaf power index, one of the most frequently used voting power measurement, is used for voting power analysis. Based on the results of the analysis, voting power distribution is affected by Turkey’s European Union membership for four coalition formation. When the Council does not act on a proposal from the Commission or the High Representative of the Union for Foreign Affairs and Security Policy, voting power distribution is not affected by Turkey’s membership for four coalition formation.
- Published
- 2013
10. The power ranking of the members of the Agricultural Committee of the European Parliament
- Author
-
Attila Kovács, Imre Fertő, Balázs Sziklai, and László Á. Kóczy
- Subjects
International relations ,Economics and Econometrics ,Banzhaf power index ,Parliament ,media_common.quotation_subject ,05 social sciences ,Public administration ,Agricultural and Biological Sciences (miscellaneous) ,Power (social and political) ,Ranking ,Voting ,Political science ,0502 economics and business ,Member state ,050207 economics ,Common Agricultural Policy ,050205 econometrics ,media_common - Abstract
We aim to identify the most influential members of the Agricultural Committee of the European Parliament (COMAGRI). Unlike previous studies that were based on case studies or interviews with stakeholders, we analyse the voting power of MEPs using a spatial Banzhaf power index. We identify critical members: members whose votes are necessary to form winning coalitions. We found that rapporteurs, EP group coordinators and MEPs from countries with high relative Committee representations, such as Ireland, Poland or Romania are powerful actors. Italy emerges as the most influential member state, while France seems surprisingly weak.
- Published
- 2020
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
11. Há desigualdade de poder entre os estados e regiões do Brasil? Uma abordagem utilizando o índice de poder de Banzhaf e a Penrose Square Root Law
- Author
-
Ana Carolina da Cruz Lima and Francisco de Sousa Ramos
- Subjects
Distribuição regional de recursos ,Desigualdades regionais ,Índice de Poder de Banzhaf ,Lei de Penrose ,Regional distribution of resources ,Regional inequality ,Banzhaf Power Index ,Penrose's Law ,Economic history and conditions ,HC10-1085 ,Economics as a science ,HB71-74 - Abstract
No Brasil sempre se discute sobre o número de representantes na Câmara Federal, com indicações de sub ou sobre-representatividade. Esta discussão tem valor político e econômico, pois uma parcela dos recursos públicos é definida nesta instância, sendo influenciada pelo efetivo poder estadual, que pode ser mensurado pelo índice de Banzhaf. Uma proposta, sugerida por Penrose, é analisada para as UF's e regiões brasileiras. A aplicação mostra que, tanto para o atual sistema quanto para o proposto, a região Sudeste é a mais favorecida. Em relação aos Estados, os mais desenvolvidos e populosos possuem maior poder de voto em ambas situações.In Brazil there are always discussions about the number of representatives in the Federal Camera, with indications of sub or super representativeness. This discussion has political and economic value because an amount of the public resources is defined in this body and it can be linked to the effective power of the states, which can be measured by the Banzhaf index. A proposal, suggested by Penrose, is analyzed for Brazilian States and Regions. Application shows that, for the current as for the Penrose system, the most favored region is the Southeast. From the viewpoint of States, it is noticed that are those more developed and populous that possess larger voting power in both situations.
- Published
- 2010
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
12. An appropriate way to extend the Banzhaf index for multiple levels of approval
- Author
-
Josep Freixas, Montserrat Pons, Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya. Departament de Matemàtiques, and Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya. GRTJ - Grup de Recerca en Teoria de Jocs
- Subjects
Index (economics) ,Relation (database) ,Computer science ,Strategy and Management ,media_common.quotation_subject ,General Decision Sciences ,Context (language use) ,Total criticality ,02 engineering and technology ,Outcome (game theory) ,Arts and Humanities (miscellaneous) ,Simple (abstract algebra) ,020204 information systems ,Management of Technology and Innovation ,Voting ,Forms of criticality ,0202 electrical engineering, electronic engineering, information engineering ,Vot -- Models matemàtics ,Voting -- Mathematical models ,Jocs, Teoria de ,Game theory ,Matemàtiques i estadística::Investigació operativa::Teoria de jocs [Àrees temàtiques de la UPC] ,media_common ,Banzhaf power index ,Extensions of the Banzhaf index ,General Social Sciences ,Extension (predicate logic) ,91 Game theory, economics, social and behavioral sciences::91A Game theory [Classificació AMS] ,Several ordered levels of input approval ,Preservation of the desirability relation ,020201 artificial intelligence & image processing ,Mathematical economics - Abstract
This is a post-peer-review, pre-copyedit version of an article published in Group decision and negotiation. The final authenticated version is available online at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10726-020-09718-7. The Banzhaf power index for games admits several extensions if the players have more than two ordered voting options. In this paper we prove that the most intu-itive and recognized extension of the index fails to preserve the desirability rela-tion for games with more than three ordered input levels of approval, a failure that undermines the index to be a good measure of power. This leads us to think of an alternative to the Banzhaf index for several input levels of approval. We propose a candidate for which it is proved that: (1) coincides with the Banzhaf index for sim-ple games, (2) it is proportional to its known extension for three levels of approval, and (3) preserves the desirability relation regardless of the number of input levels of approval. This new index is based on measuring the total capacity the player has to alter the outcome. In addition, it can be expressed through a very appropriate mathematical formulation that greatly facilitates its computation. Defining exten-sions of well-established notions in a wider context requires a careful analysis. Dif-ferent extensions can provide complementary nuances and, when this occurs, none of them can be considered to be ‘the’ extension. As shown in this paper, this situa-tion applies when trying to extend the Banzhaf power index from simple games to the broader context of games with several ordered input levels of approval. This research was partially supported by funds from: the Spanish Ministry of Economy and Competitiveness (MINECO) and from the European Union (FEDER funds) under grant MTM2015-66818-P (MINECO/FEDER), and the Spanish Ministry of Science and Innovation grant PID2019-I04987GB-I00.
- Published
- 2021
13. A MULTIFACETED ANALYSIS OF THE ELECTORAL SYSTEM OF THE REPUBLIC OF SURINAME.
- Author
-
CURIEL, Imma
- Subjects
ELECTIONS ,VOTERS ,UNICAMERALISM ,LEGISLATIVE bodies ,APPORTIONMENT (Election law) - Abstract
The electoral system of Suriname has been analyzed. Suriname has a unicameral parliament, the National Assembly. The 51 seats of the National Assembly are distributed among 10 districts. There are large discrepancies between the numbers of voters represented by a seat in the various districts. Apportionment methods leading to different seat distributions are explored and compared with each other and with the current one. The comparison is done with respect to the number of voters represented by a seat, the mean majority deficit and the probability that a majority deficit will occur, the influence of a voter in a particular district using the Banzhaf power index, and the influence of a political party relative to the percentage of the popular vote that the party obtained. The method of equal proportions turns out to yield the best results in general. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 2014
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
14. Composition independence in compound games: a characterization of the Banzhaf power index and the Banzhaf value
- Author
-
Ori Haimanko
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,Economics and Econometrics ,Banzhaf power index ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Context (language use) ,Composition (combinatorics) ,Characterization (mathematics) ,Combinatorics ,Mathematics (miscellaneous) ,Voting ,Independence (mathematical logic) ,Statistics, Probability and Uncertainty ,Value (mathematics) ,Social Sciences (miscellaneous) ,Axiom ,Mathematics ,media_common - Abstract
We introduce the axiom of composition independence for power indices and value maps. In the context of compound (two-tier) voting, the axiom requires the power attributed to a voter to be independent of the second-tier voting games played in all constituencies other than that of the voter. We show that the Banzhaf power index is uniquely characterized by the combination of composition independence, four semivalue axioms (transfer, positivity, symmetry, and dummy), and a mild efficiency-related requirement. A similar characterization is obtained as a corollary for the Banzhaf value on the space of all finite games (with transfer replaced by additivity).
- Published
- 2019
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
15. The Banzhaf value for cooperative and simple multichoice games
- Author
-
Josep Freixas, Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya. Departament de Matemàtiques, and Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya. GRTJ - Grup de Recerca en Teoria de Jocs
- Subjects
Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,Class (set theory) ,Strategy and Management ,General Decision Sciences ,02 engineering and technology ,Characterization (mathematics) ,An extension of the Banzhaf value ,Multichoice games ,Arts and Humanities (miscellaneous) ,Simple (abstract algebra) ,020204 information systems ,Management of Technology and Innovation ,0202 electrical engineering, electronic engineering, information engineering ,Vot -- Models matemàtics ,Voting -- Mathematical models ,Finite set ,Axiom ,Matemàtiques i estadística::Investigació operativa::Teoria de jocs [Àrees temàtiques de la UPC] ,Mathematics ,Cooperative games (Mathematics) ,Banzhaf power index ,ComputingMilieux_PERSONALCOMPUTING ,General Social Sciences ,Extension (predicate logic) ,91 Game theory, economics, social and behavioral sciences::91A Game theory [Classificació AMS] ,Grading ,Jocs cooperatius (Matemàtica) ,Axiomatic characterization of values ,UNSC voting system ,020201 artificial intelligence & image processing ,Mathematical economics ,Value (mathematics) - Abstract
This is a post-peer-review, pre-copyedit version of an article published in Group Decision and Negotiation. The final authenticated version is available online at: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10726-019-09651-4. This article proposes a value which can be considered an extension of the Banzhaf value for cooperative games. The proposed value is defined on the class of j-cooperative games, i.e., games in which players choose among a finite set of ordered actions and the result depends only on these elections. If the output is binary, only two options are available, then j-cooperative games become j-simple games. The restriction of the value to j-simple games leads to a power index that can be considered an extension of the Banzhaf power index for simple games. The paper provides an axiomatic characterization for the value and the index which is closely related to the first axiomatization of the Banzhaf value and Banzhaf power index in the respective contexts of cooperative and simple games.
- Published
- 2020
16. The axiom of equivalence to individual power and the Banzhaf index
- Author
-
Ori Haimanko
- Subjects
Discrete mathematics ,Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,Economics and Econometrics ,Superadditivity ,Banzhaf power index ,05 social sciences ,ComputingMilieux_PERSONALCOMPUTING ,Additive function ,0502 economics and business ,050206 economic theory ,050207 economics ,Equivalence (formal languages) ,Finance ,Axiom ,Mathematics - Abstract
I introduce a new axiom for power indices on the domain of finite simple games that requires the total power of any given pair i , j of players in any given game v to be equivalent to some individual power, i.e., equal to the power of some single player k in some game w. I show that the Banzhaf power index is uniquely characterized by this new “equivalence to individual power” axiom in conjunction with the standard semivalue axioms: transfer (which is the version of additivity adapted for simple games), symmetry or equal treatment, positivity (which is strengthened to avoid zeroing-out of the index on some games), and dummy.
- Published
- 2018
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
17. The Banzhaf power index for ternary bicooperative games
- Author
-
Bilbao, J.M., Fernández, J.R., Jiménez, N., and López, J.J.
- Subjects
- *
GAME theory , *GENERATING functions , *INDEX theorems , *COOPERATIVE processing , *MATHEMATICAL analysis - Abstract
Abstract: In this paper we analyze ternary bicooperative games, which are a refinement of the concept of a ternary voting game introduced by Felsenthal and Machover. Furthermore, majority voting rules based on the difference of votes are simple bicooperative games. First, we define the concepts of the defender and detractor swings for a player. Next, we introduce the Banzhaf power index and the normalized Banzhaf power index. The main result of the paper is an axiomatization of the Banzhaf power index for the class of ternary bicooperative games. Moreover, we study ternary bicooperative games with two lists of weights and compute the Banzhaf power index using generating functions. [Copyright &y& Elsevier]
- Published
- 2010
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
18. HÁ DESIGUALDADE DE PODER ENTRE OS ESTADOS E REGIÕES DO BRASIL? UMA ABORDAGEM UTILIZANDO O ÍNDICE DE PODER DE BANZHAF E A PENROSE SQUARE ROOT LAW.
- Author
-
da Cruz Lima, Ana Carolina and Sousa Ramos, Francisco de
- Subjects
ECONOMIC indicators ,PUBLIC sector ,VALUATION ,ECONOMIC development ,ECONOMIC value added (Corporations) - Abstract
Copyright of Brazilian Journal of Applied Economics / Economía Aplicada is the property of FEA-RP, Universidade de Sao Paulo and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use. This abstract may be abridged. No warranty is given about the accuracy of the copy. Users should refer to the original published version of the material for the full abstract. (Copyright applies to all Abstracts.)
- Published
- 2010
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
19. A Banzhaf value for games with a proximity relation among the agents
- Author
-
Andrés Jiménez-Losada, Julio R. Fernández, Manuel Ordóñez, and Inés Gallego
- Subjects
021103 operations research ,Banzhaf power index ,Applied Mathematics ,Closeness ,0211 other engineering and technologies ,02 engineering and technology ,Theoretical Computer Science ,Artificial Intelligence ,0202 electrical engineering, electronic engineering, information engineering ,Banzhaf value ,Partition (number theory) ,A priori and a posteriori ,020201 artificial intelligence & image processing ,Game theory ,Mathematical economics ,Software ,Mathematics - Abstract
The Banzhaf index is a function determining the power or influence in the decision of a set of agents. The extension of this index to the family of the cooperative games is named Banzhaf value. The relationships of closeness among the agents should modify their power. Games with a priori unions study situations where the closeness relations among the agents are taken into account. In this model the agents are organized in an a priori partition where each element of the partition represents a group of agents with close interests or ideas. The power is determined in two steps, first as a problem among the unions and later, inside each one, the power of each agent is determined. Proximity relations extend this model considering leveled closeness among the agents. In this paper we analyze a version of the Banzhaf value for games with a proximity relation and we show the interest of this value by applying it to the allocation of the power of the political groups in the European Parliament.
- Published
- 2017
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
20. Cooperative Profit Random Forests With Application in Ocean Front Recognition
- Author
-
Guoqiang Zhong, Jianyuan Sun, Qin Zhang, Junyu Dong, and Hina Saeeda
- Subjects
Random Forests ,General Computer Science ,Decision tree ,Image processing ,02 engineering and technology ,Machine learning ,computer.software_genre ,01 natural sciences ,0202 electrical engineering, electronic engineering, information engineering ,Information gain ratio ,General Materials Science ,Mathematics ,Banzhaf power index ,business.industry ,010401 analytical chemistry ,General Engineering ,Cooperative game theory ,Regression ,0104 chemical sciences ,Random forest ,Tree (data structure) ,020201 artificial intelligence & image processing ,Artificial intelligence ,Data mining ,lcsh:Electrical engineering. Electronics. Nuclear engineering ,business ,Game theory ,computer ,cooperative game theory ,lcsh:TK1-9971 - Abstract
Random Forests are powerful classification and regression tools that are commonly applied in machine learning and image processing. In the majority of random classification forests algorithms, the Gini index and the information gain ratio are commonly used for node splitting. However, these two kinds of node-split methods may pay less attention to the intrinsic structure of the attribute variables and fail to find attributes with strong discriminate ability as a group yet weak as individuals. In this paper, we propose an innovative method for splitting the tree nodes based on the cooperative game theory, from which some attributes with good discriminate ability as a group can be learned. This new random forests algorithm is called Cooperative Profit Random Forests (CPRF). Experimental comparisons with several other existing random classification forests algorithms are carried out on several real-world data sets, including remote sensing images. The results show that CPRF outperforms other existing Random Forests algorithms in most cases. In particular, CPRF achieves promising results in ocean front recognition.
- Published
- 2017
21. Evaluation of Power Distribution among the European Political Groups in the European Parliament in 1979-2014
- Author
-
R.U. Kamalova
- Subjects
Index (economics) ,Sociology and Political Science ,Banzhaf power index ,Public economics ,Parliament ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Cardinal voting systems ,Microeconomics ,Power (social and political) ,Politics ,Voting ,Political science ,Political Science and International Relations ,Pairwise comparison ,media_common - Abstract
The author analyzes the power distribution among political groups in the European Parliament from 1979 till 2014. Agent’s voting power is treated as the capability to influence the result of collective decision-making process. Often the voting power is not equal to votes share the agent possess. We obtain the values of classical and modified power indices for European political groups and compare their performance. The Banzhaf power index is employed to measure European political groups’ a priori power that does not impose any restrictions on coalition formation, and power indices that take into account groups’ preferences in coalition formation in order to measure actual voting power. Classical power indices are calculated using only votes’ distribution in the committee and a quota to pass a decision. Pairwise preferences allow to have respect to different willingness of groups to form a single coalition. In this paper preferences are modeled using the roll-call data from the votings on important issues of European politics. The less popular is the MP’s position, the smaller is the number of coalitions she can enter and the less is the voting power. We demonstrate that factions can exploit their position and acquire higher relative power than both share of seats and the Banzhaf index measures, and the Liberal group of the European Parliament forming coalitions with both partners from the left and the right is the case. Conversely, hard restrictions on formation of coalitions due to ideological differences can lead to less actual voting power than a priori.
- Published
- 2016
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
22. False‐Name Manipulation in Weighted Voting Games: Empirical and Theoretical Analysis
- Author
-
Vicki H. Allan and Ramoni O. Lasisi
- Subjects
Shapley–Shubik power index ,Class (set theory) ,021103 operations research ,Banzhaf power index ,Computer science ,Open problem ,Multi-agent system ,0211 other engineering and technologies ,Weighted voting ,02 engineering and technology ,16. Peace & justice ,Computational Mathematics ,Artificial Intelligence ,Unanimity ,0202 electrical engineering, electronic engineering, information engineering ,020201 artificial intelligence & image processing ,Mathematical economics ,Complement (set theory) - Abstract
Weighted voting games are important in multiagent systems because of their usage in automated decision making. However, they are not immune from the vulnerability of false-name manipulation by strategic agents that may be present in the games. False-name manipulation involves an agent splitting its weight among several false identities in anticipation of power increase. Previous works have considered false-name manipulation using the well-known Shapley–Shubik and Banzhaf power indices. Bounds on the extent of power that a manipulator may gain exist when it splits into k = 2 false identities for both the Shapley–Shubik and Banzhaf indices. The bounds when an agent splits into k > 2 false identities, until now, have remained open for the two indices. This article answers this open problem by providing four nontrivial bounds when an agent splits into k > 2 false identities for the two indices. Furthermore, we propose a new bound on the extent of power that a manipulator may gain when it splits into several false identities in a class of games referred to as excess unanimity weighted voting games. Finally, we complement our theoretical results with empirical evaluation. Results from our experiments confirm the existence of beneficial splits into several false identities for the two indices, and also establish that splitting into more than two false identities is qualitatively different than the previously known splitting into exactly two false identities.
- Published
- 2016
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
23. Combined Banzhaf & Diversity Index (CBDI) for critical node detection
- Author
-
Waqar Asif, Marios Lestas, Muttukrishnan Rajarajan, and Hassaan Khaliq Qureshi
- Subjects
QA75 ,Algebraic connectivity ,computer_science ,Theoretical computer science ,Banzhaf power index ,Computer Networks and Communications ,Network security ,business.industry ,Computer science ,Node (networking) ,Reliability (computer networking) ,020206 networking & telecommunications ,02 engineering and technology ,Network topology ,01 natural sciences ,Computer Science Applications ,Hardware and Architecture ,Robustness (computer science) ,0103 physical sciences ,Metric (mathematics) ,0202 electrical engineering, electronic engineering, information engineering ,Network performance ,010306 general physics ,business - Abstract
Critical node discovery plays a vital role in assessing the vulnerability of a computer network to malicious attacks and failures and provides a useful tool with which one can greatly improve network security and reliability. In this paper, we propose a new metric to characterize the criticality of a node in an arbitrary computer network which we refer to as the Combined Banzhaf & Diversity Index (CBDI). The metric utilizes a diversity index which is based on the variability of a node׳s attributes relative to its neighbours and the Banzhaf power index which characterizes the degree of participation of a node in forming shortest paths. The Banzhaf power index is inspired from the theory of voting games in game theory. The proposed metric is evaluated using analysis and simulations. The criticality of nodes in a network is assessed based on the degradation in network performance achieved when these nodes are removed. We use several performance metrics to evaluate network performance including the algebraic connectivity which is a spectral metric characterizing the connectivity robustness of the network. Extensive simulations in a number of network topologies indicate that the proposed CBDI index chooses more critical nodes which, when removed, degrade network performance to a greater extent than if critical nodes based on other criticality metrics were removed.
- Published
- 2016
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
24. THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN SHAREHOLDING CONCENTRATION AND SHAREHOLDER VOTING POWER IN BRITISH COMPANIES: A STUDY OF THE APPLICATION OF POWER INDICES FOR SIMPLE GAMES.
- Author
-
Leech, Dennis
- Subjects
STOCKHOLDERS ,STOCKHOLDERS' voting ,STOCKHOLDERS' meetings ,STOCKS (Finance) ,BUSINESS enterprises ,BRITISH corporations ,CORPORATE power ,VOTING - Abstract
This paper reports an analysis of the relationships between shareholding and voting power distributions in a sample of British companies. It applies two standard approaches to the measurement of power in simple games: the Shapley-Shubik and the Banzhaf power indices. The results indicate that power is more concentrated than ownership in every case. A comparison of the two indices reveals that typically the Banzhaf index gives a more concentrated power distribution. For the Shapley-Shubik index the power ratio for the largest shareholder is accurately described in terms of the size of holding and the concentration of the remainder. The corresponding Banzhaf power ratio is less dependent on these variables. There is no association between power concentration and company size. [ABSTRACT FROM AUTHOR]
- Published
- 1988
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
25. Generating Functions of Weighted Voting Games, MacMahon’s Partition Analysis, and Clifford Algebras
- Author
-
Antônio Francisco Neto
- Subjects
Shapley–Shubik power index ,Discrete mathematics ,021103 operations research ,Banzhaf power index ,General Mathematics ,Diophantine equation ,Clifford algebra ,0211 other engineering and technologies ,Weighted voting ,Context (language use) ,02 engineering and technology ,Management Science and Operations Research ,Computer Science Applications ,Partition analysis ,Mathematics - Abstract
MacMahon’s Partition Analysis (MPA) is a combinatorial tool used in partition analysis to describe the solutions of a linear diophantine system. We show that MPA is useful in the context of weighte...
- Published
- 2018
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
26. Producer heterogeneity and voting power in mandatory US agricultural marketing organisations
- Author
-
Zoe T. Plakias and Rachael E. Goodhue
- Subjects
Economics and Econometrics ,Index (economics) ,Banzhaf power index ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Theory of the firm ,Agricultural and Biological Sciences (miscellaneous) ,Microeconomics ,Market structure ,Promotion (rank) ,Agricultural marketing ,Voting ,Economics ,Market power ,Industrial organization ,media_common - Abstract
© Oxford University Press and Foundation for the European Review of Agricultural Economics 2015.We consider how cost heterogeneity and market power affect voting power in producer referenda for mandatory agricultural marketing organisations with generic promotion programmes in the United States. We measure voting power using the Banzhaf Power Index and propose a new version of this index based on the profit-maximising theory of the firm that provides an improved estimate of voting power. Examining several types of demand shifts and voting rules, we find that both Banzhaf Power and our new measure vary considerably depending on the market structure and level of cost heterogeneity.
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
27. Stochastic asymmetric Blotto games: Some new results
- Author
-
John Duffy and Alexander Matros
- Subjects
Economics and Econometrics ,Majority rule ,Non-cooperative game ,Banzhaf power index ,CONTEST ,Microeconomics ,symbols.namesake ,Lottery ,Strategy ,Nash equilibrium ,Economics ,symbols ,Resource allocation ,Mathematical economics ,Finance - Abstract
Stochastic Asymmetric Blotto Games: Some New Results John Duffy ∗ Abstract. Blotto games. Alexander Matros † We develop some new theoretical results for stochastic asymmetric Keywords: Colonel Blotto game, Contests, Resource Allocation, Lotteries. JEL Classification Nos. C72, C73, D72, D74. 1. Introduction The Colonel Blotto game (Borel 1921), is a two-player non-cooperative game in which players decide how to allocate their given resources across battlefields. In Borel’s original version of this game, the player who allocates the most resources to any given battlefield wins that battlefield with certainty. The players’ objective function is either to maximize the sum of the value of the battlefields won, or to win a majority value of the battlefields. In this paper we study stochastic asymmetric versions of the Blotto game under both of these objective functions. In an “asymmetric Blotto” game, the values of the battlefields may differ from one another though these different values are common to all players. In the “stochastic asymmetric” version of the Blotto game, the deterministic rule for determining which player wins each battlefield is replaced by a lottery contest success function where the chances of winning a given battlefield are increasing with the amount of resources devoted to that battlefield. This stochastic lottery specification makes the payoff function continuous; as a result, if a Nash equilibrium exists, it is unique and in pure strategies, as opposed to the multiplicity of (typically mixed strategy) equilibria that arise in deterministic versions of the Blotto game. There are two main theoretical papers about stochastic asymmetric Blotto games. 1 The first one, Friedman (1958), considers two players who seek to maximize their expected total payoff. We show that Friedman’s result can be extended to any number of players. The second paper, Lake (1979), was the first to study the stochastic asymmetric “majority rule” Blotto game. 2 This version of the game is particularly relevant to understanding electoral competitions in two party systems, e.g., the electoral college system for electing the U.S. president. Lake studied only the case of equal budget constraints. We show that if players’ budgets are the same (as in Lake) or if they are sufficiently similar and the number of items (battlefields) is not too large, then resource allocation under the majority rule version of the stochastic, asymmetric Blotto game is proportional to the Banzhaf power index for each item, while more generally, resource allocation for a particular item will not be proportional to each item’s Banzhaf power index. Our findings thus generalize those of Lake (1979). Department of Economics, University of California, Irvine. Email: duffy@uci.edu. Moore School of Business, University of South Carolina and Lancaster University Management School. Email: alexander.matros@gmail.com See Kovenock and Roberson (2012) for a broader survey of the Blotto game literature. We discovered Lake’s (1979) paper only after we had completed our analysis. His proofs are different from ours, but his main result coincides with our prediction for the case of equal budgets. We thank Steve Brams for providing this reference.
- Published
- 2015
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
28. Unilateral effects screens for partial horizontal acquisitions: The generalized HHI and GUPPI
- Author
-
Universitat Rovira i Virgili, Brito D; Osório A; Ribeiro R; Vasconcelos H, Universitat Rovira i Virgili, and Brito D; Osório A; Ribeiro R; Vasconcelos H
- Abstract
© 2018 Elsevier B.V. Recent years have witnessed an increased interest, by competition agencies, in assessing the competitive effects of partial acquisitions. We propose a generalization of the two most traditional indicators used to screen unilateral anti-competitive effects - the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index and the Gross Upward Price Pressure Index - to partial horizontal acquisition settings. The proposed generalized indicators are endogenously derived under a probabilistic voting model in which the manager of each firm is elected in a shareholder assembly between two potential candidates who seek to obtain utility from an exogenous rent associated with corporate office. The model (i) can cope with settings involving all types of owners and rights: owners that can be internal to the industry (rival firms) and external to the industry; and rights that can capture financial and corporate control interests, can be direct and indirect, can be partial or full, (ii) yields an endogenous measure of the owners ultimate corporate control rights, and (iii) can also be used - in case the potential acquisition is inferred to likely enhance market power - to devise divestiture structural remedies. We also provide an empirical application of the two proposed generalized indicators to several acquisitions in the wet shaving industry, with the objective of providing practitioners with a step-by-step illustration of how to compute them in antitrust cases.
- Published
- 2018
29. Unilateral effects screens for partial horizontal acquisitions: the generalized HHI and GUPPI
- Author
-
António Osório, Helder Vasconcelos, Ricardo Ribeiro, Duarte Brito, Veritati - Repositório Institucional da Universidade Católica Portuguesa, Universitat Rovira i Virgili. Centre de Recerca en Economia Industrial i Economia Pública, and Universitat Rovira i Virgili. Departament d'Economia
- Subjects
Economics and Econometrics ,Corporate control ,Index (economics) ,HHI ,Strategy and Management ,Oligopolis ,Economics, Econometrics and Finance (miscellaneous) ,Control (management) ,Competència econòmica -- Dret i legislació ,Monopolis ,GUPPI ,jel:L41 ,33 - Economia ,Microeconomics ,Competition (economics) ,Oligopoly ,jel:L66 ,Shareholder ,Screening indicators ,0502 economics and business ,050602 political science & public administration ,Partial horizontal acquisitions ,Market power ,050207 economics ,Special case ,Industrial organization ,health care economics and organizations ,050208 finance ,Banzhaf power index ,05 social sciences ,Price pressure ,0506 political science ,Industrial relations ,jel:L13 ,Probabilistic voting model ,Business ,Antitrust, Partial Horizontal Acquisitions, Oligopoly, Screening Indicators, HHI, GUPPI ,Divestment - Abstract
Recent years have witnessed an increased interest, by competition agencies, in assessing the competitive effects of partial acquisitions. We propose a generalization to a partial horizontal acquisition setting of the two most traditional indicators used to screen unilateral anti-competitive effects: the Helfindahl- Hirschman Index and the Gross Upward Price Pressure Index. The proposed generalized indicators can deal with all types of acquisitions that may lessen competition in the industry: acquisitions by owners that are internal to the industry (rival firms) and engage in cross-ownership, as well as acquisitions by owners that are external to the industry and engage in common-ownership. Furthermore, these indicators can deal with direct and indirect acquisitions, which may or may not correspond to control, and nest full mergers as a special case. We provide an empirical application to several acquisitions in the wet shaving industry. The results seem to suggest that (i) a full merger induces higher unilateral anti-competitive effects than a partial controlling acquisition involving the same firms, (ii) a partial controlling acquisition induces higher unilateral anti-competitive effects than a partial non-controlling acquisition involving the same firms and the same financial stakes, and (iii) an acquisition by owners that are internal to the industry induces higher unilateral anti-competitive effects than an acquisition (involving the same firms and the same stakes) by external owners that participate in more than one competitor firm. JEL Classification: L13, L41, L66 Keywords: Antitrust, Partial Horizontal Acquisitions, Oligopoly, Screening Indicators, HHI, GUPPI
- Published
- 2018
30. Banzhaf random forests: Cooperative game theory based random forests with consistency
- Author
-
Guoqiang Zhong, Kaizhu Huang, Jianyuan Sun, and Junyu Dong
- Subjects
Support Vector Machine ,Computer science ,Cognitive Neuroscience ,02 engineering and technology ,Machine learning ,computer.software_genre ,03 medical and health sciences ,Random Allocation ,0302 clinical medicine ,Game Theory ,Artificial Intelligence ,Consistency (statistics) ,0202 electrical engineering, electronic engineering, information engineering ,Information gain ratio ,Feature (machine learning) ,Cluster Analysis ,Humans ,Structure (mathematical logic) ,Banzhaf power index ,business.industry ,Cooperative game theory ,Random forest ,Support vector machine ,020201 artificial intelligence & image processing ,Artificial intelligence ,business ,computer ,030217 neurology & neurosurgery ,Algorithms - Abstract
Random forests algorithms have been widely used in many classification and regression applications. However, the theory of random forests lags far behind their applications. In this paper, we propose a novel random forests classification algorithm based on cooperative game theory. The Banzhaf power index is employed to evaluate the power of each feature by traversing possible feature coalitions. Hence, we call the proposed algorithm Banzhaf random forests (BRFs). Unlike the previously used information gain ratio, which only measures the power of each feature for classification and pays less attention to the intrinsic structure of the feature variables, the Banzhaf power index can measure the importance of each feature by computing the dependency among the group of features. More importantly, we have proved the consistency of BRFs, which narrows the gap between the theory and applications of random forests. Extensive experiments on several UCI benchmark data sets and three real world applications show that BRFs perform significantly better than existing consistent random forests on classification accuracy, and better than or at least comparable with Breiman's random forests, support vector machines (SVMs) and k-nearest neighbors (KNNs) classifiers.
- Published
- 2017
31. The Visegrád Group – A Rising Star Post-Brexit? Changing Distribution of Power in the European Council
- Author
-
Ralf Thomas Göllner
- Subjects
coalition building ,media_common.quotation_subject ,ddc:320 ,voting power ,International trade ,Profit (economics) ,Politics ,Political science ,Voting ,media_common.cataloged_instance ,European union ,Visegrád countries ,European Council ,Brexit ,media_common ,International relations ,Banzhaf power index ,business.industry ,visegrád countries ,european council ,Economy ,Voting behavior ,320 Politik ,business ,brexit - Abstract
The portmanteau Brexit describes the withdrawal of the United Kingdom (UK) from the European Union (EU) which will cause a shift of power in the European institutions. The departure of one of the largest EU members will affect the voting power of member countries in the European Council significantly. This Council is the central hub of political decision making in the EU, defining the overall political direction and priorities and setting the policy agenda for the entirety of the EU. Using the Banzhaf power index, we have measured the voting power before and after the Brexit and analyzed the increasing power of the members of the Visegrád Group compared to other European states. We have found that there is growth in the voting power of all Visegrád states, with Poland experiencing the biggest increase. However, the extent by which the Visegrád Group will profit from this statistically growing power depends on the coordination of their voting behavior in the future.
- Published
- 2017
32. Power theories for multi-choice organizations and political rules: Rank-order equivalence
- Author
-
Narcisse Tedjeugang, Roland Pongou, and Bertrand Tchantcho
- Subjects
Statistics and Probability ,Large class ,Discrete mathematics ,Control and Optimization ,Banzhaf power index ,Strategy and Management ,media_common.quotation_subject ,lcsh:Mathematics ,Management Science and Operations Research ,lcsh:QA1-939 ,(j ,Politics ,If and only if ,Voting ,Multi-choice organizations and political rules ,(j,k) voting rules ,Rank-order equivalence ,ddc:330 ,Power theories ,k) voting rules ,Equivalence (measure theory) ,Mathematical economics ,media_common ,Mathematics - Abstract
Voting power theories measure the ability of voters to influence the outcome of an election under a given voting rule. In general, each theory gives a different evaluation of power, raising the question of their appropriateness, and calling for the need to identify classes of rules for which different theories agree. We study the ordinal equivalence of the generalizations of the classical power concepts–the influence relation, the Banzhaf power index, and the Shapley–Shubik power index–to multi-choice organizations and political rules. Under such rules, each voter chooses a level of support for a social goal from a finite list of options, and these individual choices are aggregated to determine the collective level of support for this goal. We show that the power theories analyzed do not always yield the same power relationships among voters. Thanks to necessary and/or sufficient conditions, we identify a large class of rules for which ordinal equivalence obtains. Furthermore, we prove that ordinal equivalence obtains for all linear rules allowing a fixed number of individual approval levels if and only if that number does not exceed three. Our findings generalize all the previous results on the ordinal equivalence of the classical power theories, and show that the condition of linearity found to be necessary and sufficient for ordinal equivalence to obtain when voters have at most three options to choose from is no longer sufficient when they can choose from a list of four or more options.
- Published
- 2014
33. Genişlemelerle Birlikte Avrupa Birliği Bakanlar Konseyi’nde Oylama Gücü Dağılımı(Voting Power Distribution With The Enlargements In The Council of The European Union)
- Author
-
Hatice Burcu ESKİCİ and Özgür YENİAY
- Subjects
Treaty of Lisbon ,lcsh:Management. Industrial management ,lcsh:HD28-70 ,lcsh:HB71-74 ,Banzhaf power index ,lcsh:Economics as a science ,European Union - Abstract
Nowadays, enlargement is one of the most important issue for European Union. The situation that makes this issue important is the influence of membership of the candidate states on the voting power distribution. With the enlargements, European Union decision-making processes were regulated several times. The last regulation to the European Union voting system was brought by the Treaty of Lisbon. In this study, voting power distribution in Council of the European Union is evaluated for candidate states and member states considering the acts adopted by the Treaty of Lisbon and determined as candidate states determined as Turkey, Croatia, Iceland, Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia. In the analysis, member states are grouped the according to the enlargement of the EU and the effect of the states that take part in these groups on the decision and changes of voting power are calculated using Banzhaf power index for power measurement.
- Published
- 2013
34. Computing cooperative solution concepts in coalitional skill games
- Author
-
Yoram Bachrach, Jeffrey S. Rosenschein, and David C. Parkes
- Subjects
Linguistics and Language ,Theoretical computer science ,Computational complexity theory ,Banzhaf power index ,Computer science ,TheoryofComputation_GENERAL ,ComputingMethodologies_ARTIFICIALINTELLIGENCE ,Shapley value ,Language and Linguistics ,Task (project management) ,Core (game theory) ,Cover (topology) ,Artificial Intelligence ,If and only if ,Set (psychology) ,Mathematical economics - Abstract
We consider a simple model of cooperation among agents called Coalitional Skill Games (CSGs). This is a restricted form of coalitional games, where each agent has a set of skills that are required to complete various tasks. Each task requires a set of skills in order to be completed, and a coalition can accomplish the task only if the coalition@?s agents cover the set of required skills for the task. The gain for a coalition depends only on the subset of tasks it can complete. We consider the computational complexity of several problems in CSGs, such as testing if an agent is a dummy or veto agent, computing the core and core-related solution concepts, and computing power indices such as the Shapley value and Banzhaf power index.
- Published
- 2013
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
35. Enumeration of weighted games with minimum and an analysis of voting power for bipartite complete games with minimum
- Author
-
Sascha Kurz, Josep Freixas, Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya. Departament de Matemàtica Aplicada III, and Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya. GRTJ - Grup de Recerca en Teoria de Jocs
- Subjects
Ordinal equivalence ,System ,Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Semivalues ,Simple game ,General Decision Sciences ,Management Science and Operations Research ,Type (model theory) ,Combinatorics ,Enumerations ,Europena Union ,Simple (abstract algebra) ,Weighted and complete games ,Voting ,FOS: Mathematics ,91 Game theory, economics, social and behavioral sciences::91B Mathematical economics [Classificació AMS] ,Enumeration ,Mathematics - Combinatorics ,Rank (graph theory) ,Vot -- Models matemàtics ,Jocs, Teoria de ,Special case ,Shapley-Shubik power index ,Matemàtiques i estadística::Investigació operativa::Teoria de jocs [Àrees temàtiques de la UPC] ,Game theory ,Mathematics ,media_common ,Discrete mathematics ,Shapley–Shubik power index ,Banzhaf power indices ,Banzhaf power index ,ComputingMilieux_PERSONALCOMPUTING ,Indexes ,91 Game theory, economics, social and behavioral sciences::91A Game theory [Classificació AMS] ,Bipartite graph ,Voting--Mathematical models ,Council ,Combinatorics (math.CO) ,91A12, 91A40, 91A80, 91B12 ,Dimension ,Focus (optics) - Abstract
This paper is a twofold contribution. First, it contributes to the problem of enumerating some classes of simple games and in particular provides the number of weighted games with minimum and the number of weighted games for the dual class as well. Second, we focus on the special case of bipartite complete games with minimum, and we compare and rank these games according to the behavior of some efficient power indices of players of type 1 (or of type 2). The main result of this second part establishes all allowable rankings of these games when the Shapley-Shubik power index is used on players of type 1., 26 pages, 2 figures, to appear in Annals of Operations Research
- Published
- 2013
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
36. Banzhaf voting power, random elections, and the Electoral College winner’s advantage
- Author
-
Nicholas R. Miller
- Subjects
Banzhaf power index ,Spoilt vote ,Public economics ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Victory ,Power (social and political) ,Contingent vote ,Margin (machine learning) ,Voting ,Political Science and International Relations ,Econometrics ,Economics ,Electoral college ,media_common - Abstract
In a recent article, Riggs et al. (2009) aim to measure the ‘Electoral College winner's advantage’—in particular, the extent to which the winner’s electoral vote margin of victory is magnified as a result of (i) the ‘two electoral vote add-on’ given to each state and (ii) the ‘winner-take-all’ mode of casting state electoral votes. Their results are based on two sets of one million simulated two-candidate elections. This note has two purposes. The first is to demonstrate that RHR’s simulation estimates can be calculated precisely using the theory of voting power measurement. The second is to correct several flaws in RHR’s analysis, the most substantial of which pertains to the effect of the two electoral vote add-on, which actually has a negative effect on the winner’s advantage.
- Published
- 2011
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
37. Approximating power indices: theoretical and empirical analysis
- Author
-
Yoram Bachrach, Evangelos Markakis, Ezra Resnick, Ariel D. Procaccia, Amin Saberi, and Jeffrey S. Rosenschein
- Subjects
Shapley–Shubik power index ,Mathematical optimization ,Banzhaf power index ,Computer science ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Weighted voting ,Approximation algorithm ,Outcome (game theory) ,Shapley value ,Randomized algorithm ,Artificial Intelligence ,Voting ,Representation (mathematics) ,media_common - Abstract
Many multiagent domains where cooperation among agents is crucial to achieving a common goal can be modeled as coalitional games. However, in many of these domains, agents are unequal in their power to affect the outcome of the game. Prior research on weighted voting games has explored power indices, which reflect how much "real power" a voter has. Although primarily used for voting games, these indices can be applied to any simple coalitional game. Computing these indices is known to be computationally hard in various domains, so one must sometimes resort to approximate methods for calculating them. We suggest and analyze randomized methods to approximate power indices such as the Banzhaf power index and the Shapley---Shubik power index. Our approximation algorithms do not depend on a specific representation of the game, so they can be used in any simple coalitional game. Our methods are based on testing the game's value for several sample coalitions. We show that no approximation algorithm can do much better for general coalitional games, by providing lower bounds for both deterministic and randomized algorithms for calculating power indices. We also provide empirical results regarding our method, and show that it typically achieves much better accuracy and confidence than those required.
- Published
- 2009
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
38. Actual voting power of the IMF members based on their political-economic integration
- Author
-
Kirill Pogorelskiy, Fuad Aleskerov, and Valeriy A. Kalyagin
- Subjects
Anti-plurality voting ,Majority rule ,Banzhaf power index ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Weighted voting ,Penrose method ,Computer Science Applications ,Cardinal voting systems ,Modelling and Simulation ,Modeling and Simulation ,Voting ,Econometrics ,Algorithm ,media_common ,Mathematics ,Preferential block voting - Abstract
A voting power analysis was made to estimate the power of IMF members within the Executive Board and the Fund in general through the existing constituency system. For this purpose we introduced two absolute power indices extending the classical Penrose (non-normalized Banzhaf) and Coleman (''the power of the body to act'') indices by taking into account the members' preferences to coalesce, based on their membership in the currently functioning political-economic blocs with varying degrees of economic integration and members' regional proximity as well. We considered an indirect voting system where countries are contending for power at two levels: within their constituencies and within the Executive Board. Accordingly, each of the proposed power indices determines a member's power at the appropriate level. The total power of a country is then defined by a compound power index, which is the product of the above-mentioned indices. Experiments displayed the robustness of the indices to small variations in the weight coefficients assigned to the preferences considered. Using our approach, we analysed countries' voting power within the Executive Board under the three cases of majority voting adopted by the IMF, namely, a simple majority and qualified majorities of 70% and 85% of the total votes. The power indices for all members (except those with voting rights suspended) and their constituencies were calculated and compared with the Penrose and Banzhaf indices. The results show that members' absolute voting power as measured by our indices produces a power distribution different from that of Penrose and Banzhaf power in both directions. The constituencies' relative voting power is rather close to their IMF voting weights for the case of the simple majority voting and tends to redistribute between constituencies as the threshold number of votes for a decision to be taken increases; thus, for the 85% supermajority, the maximum power share is that of the Netherlands's constituency and not that of the US's, as the Banzhaf power index suggests.
- Published
- 2008
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
39. Evaluation of Banzhaf index with restrictions on coalitions formation
- Author
-
Vyacheslav Yakuba
- Subjects
Polynomial ,Index (economics) ,Banzhaf power index ,Modeling and Simulation ,Modelling and Simulation ,Generating function ,Representation (mathematics) ,Mathematical economics ,Mathematics ,Computer Science Applications - Abstract
The generating functions representative of the Banzhaf power index of the parties, or political groups of electoral bodies, is applied to the case where particular parties simultaneously (in pairs) cannot be part of any coalition. For such types of restrictions on coalition formation, the two-stage procedure for evaluating the Banzhaf index using generating functions is presented. Throughout the steps of the procedure the adjusted Banzhaf index generating function polynomial is transformed to the standard representation used for the calculation of this index. The presented approach is discussed and the procedure is illustrated by several examples.
- Published
- 2008
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
40. Computing the Power Distribution in the IMF
- Author
-
Sascha Kurz
- Subjects
FOS: Computer and information sciences ,Banzhaf power index ,business.industry ,91B12, 91A12 ,Computation ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Weighted voting ,Distribution (economics) ,Special drawing rights ,Power (physics) ,Dynamic programming ,Computer Science - Computer Science and Game Theory ,Voting ,Economics ,business ,Mathematical economics ,Computer Science and Game Theory (cs.GT) ,media_common - Abstract
The International Monetary Fund is one of the largest international organizations using a weighted voting system. The weights of its 188 members are determined by a fixed amount of basic votes plus some extra votes for so-called Special Drawing Rights (SDR). On January 26, 2016, the conditions for the SDRs were increased at the 14th General Quota Review, which drastically changed the corresponding voting weights. However, since the share of voting weights in general is not equal to the influence, of a committee member on the committees overall decision, so-called power indices were introduced. So far the power distribution of the IMF was only computed by either approximation procedures or smaller games than then entire Board of Governors consisting of 188 members. We improve existing algorithms, based on dynamic programming, for the computation of power indices and provide the exact results for the IMF Board of Governors before and after the increase of voting weights. Tuned low-level details of the algorithms allow the repeated routine with sparse computational resources and can of course be applied to other large voting bodies. It turned out that the Banzhaf power shares are rather sensitive to changes of the quota., Comment: 19 pages, 2 figures, 13 tables
- Published
- 2016
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
41. Computing Banzhaf–Coleman and Shapley–Shubik power indices with incompatible players
- Author
-
José María Alonso-Meijide, Balbina Casas-Méndez, and M. G. Fiestras-Janeiro
- Subjects
Shapley–Shubik power index ,1207.06 Teoría de Juegos ,Computational Mathematics ,Banzhaf power index ,Applied Mathematics ,ComputingMilieux_PERSONALCOMPUTING ,TheoryofComputation_GENERAL ,Mathematical economics ,Power (physics) ,Mathematics - Abstract
In this paper, we present methods to compute Banzhaf–Coleman and Shapley–Shubik power indices for weighted majority games when some players are incompatible. We use the so-called generating functions as a tool. Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación | Ref. MTM2011-27731-C03
- Published
- 2015
42. Coalition Configurations and the Banzhaf Index
- Author
-
M. Josune Albizuri and Jesus Aurrekoetxea
- Subjects
Economics and Econometrics ,Index (economics) ,Banzhaf power index ,Generalization ,MathematicsofComputing_GENERAL ,Economics ,TheoryofComputation_GENERAL ,Join (topology) ,Mathematical economics ,Social Sciences (miscellaneous) - Abstract
In this paper, we suppose that players join in coalitions and form a coalition configuration, and we provide a generalization of the normalized Banzhaf-Coleman (1965, 1971) index to this framework.
- Published
- 2006
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
43. A NEW CHARACTERIZATION OF THE BANZHAF INDEX OF POWER
- Author
-
Satya R. Chakravarty, Rana Barua, and Sonali Roy
- Subjects
Index (economics) ,General Computer Science ,Banzhaf power index ,Characterization (mathematics) ,jel:M2 ,Power (physics) ,Mathematics::Logic ,jel:C0 ,C71, JEL Classification Numbers: D72, Primary: 91A06, Secondary: 91A40 [Voting game, voting power, Banzhaf index, axioms, characterization, JEL Classification Numbers] ,Independence (mathematical logic) ,jel:D5 ,Statistics, Probability and Uncertainty ,Business and International Management ,jel:B4 ,jel:C6 ,jel:D7 ,Mathematical economics ,jel:C7 ,Axiom ,Mathematics - Abstract
This paper develops a new axiomatic characterization of the Banzhaf index of power using four axioms from four different contributions to the area. A nice feature of the characterization is independence of the axioms showing importance of each of them in the exercise.
- Published
- 2005
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
44. A decisiveness index for simple games
- Author
-
Francesc Carreras
- Subjects
Information Systems and Management ,Index (economics) ,General Computer Science ,Banzhaf power index ,Close relationship ,Simple (abstract algebra) ,Modeling and Simulation ,Mathematical properties ,Management Science and Operations Research ,Measure (mathematics) ,Mathematical economics ,Industrial and Manufacturing Engineering ,Axiom - Abstract
The decisiveness index introduced in this paper is designed to provide a normalized measure of the agility of all simple games, primarily viewed as collective decision-making mechanisms. We study the mathematical properties of the index and derive different axiomatic characterizations for it. Moreover, a close relationship is shown to the Banzhaf index of power––for which twice the decisiveness index plays the role of potential function––that gives rise to an effective computational procedure. Some real-world examples illustrate the usefulness of the decisiveness index, together with the Banzhaf power index, in applications to political science.
- Published
- 2005
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
45. Valuation of voting scheme changes the cases of Electrolux AB and SKF AB
- Author
-
Yinghong Chen
- Subjects
Banzhaf power index ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Corporate governance ,ComputingMilieux_LEGALASPECTSOFCOMPUTING ,Share price ,General Business, Management and Accounting ,Shareholder ,Voting ,Value (economics) ,Econometrics ,Stock market ,Business ,Valuation (finance) ,media_common - Abstract
This paper studies the effects of a voting scheme change on the stock market prices of Electrolux and SKF AB using standard event study methodology and a clinical approach. The economic effect of the voting scheme change is assessed using the market model. We investigate the loss of control due to the change in the voting scheme. The degree of change in power is calculated using the Shapley-Shubik power index and the Banzhaf power index. There is a wealth transfer from the high vote shareholders to the low vote shareholders in the process since in both cases the high vote shareholders required no compensation. We expect share price to respond positively to an announcement of a forthcoming voting scheme change, due to the reduced power discount and corporate governance improvement. The magnitude of the response on the event day depends also on the information structure of the period leading up to the announcement. A bigger effect on the value of the firm is to be expected if the voting powers of the major owner(s) shift away from absolute control to moderate control, indicating a significant change in governance pattern.
- Published
- 2004
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
46. [Untitled]
- Author
-
Adrian Van Deemen and Agnieszka Rusinowska
- Subjects
Economics and Econometrics ,Sociology and Political Science ,Banzhaf power index ,Parliament ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Welfare economics ,Politics ,Redistribution (election) ,Voting ,Political science ,Mathematical economics ,Large size ,media_common ,Public finance - Abstract
In this paper we first evaluate thirteen seat distributions inthe Second Chamber of the Dutch parliament by means of severalindices of voting power. Subsequently, we search for theoccurrence of the paradox of redistribution, the paradox ofnew members, and the paradox of large size for each powerindex. The indices used are the Shapley-Shubik index, thenormalized Banzhaf index, the Penrose-Banzhaf index, theHoller index, and the Deegan-Packel index.
- Published
- 2003
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
47. Voting power in the European Union enlargement
- Author
-
Jesús Mario Bilbao, J. J. López, Julio R. Fernández, and N. Jiménez
- Subjects
Anti-plurality voting ,Information Systems and Management ,General Computer Science ,Banzhaf power index ,Council of Ministers ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Decision rule ,Management Science and Operations Research ,Industrial and Manufacturing Engineering ,Modeling and Simulation ,Voting ,Economics ,media_common.cataloged_instance ,European union ,Mathematical economics ,Time complexity ,media_common ,Treaty of Nice - Abstract
The Shapley–Shubik power index in a voting situation depends on the number of orderings in which each player is pivotal. The Banzhaf power index depends on the number of ways in which each voter can effect a swing. If there are n players in a voting situation, then the function which measures the worst case running time for computing these indices is in O( n 2 n ). We present a combinatorial method based in generating functions to compute these power indices efficiently in weighted double or triple majority games and we study the time complexity of the algorithms. Moreover, we calculate these power indices for the countries in the Council of Ministers of the European Union under the new decision rules prescribed by the Treaty of Nice.
- Published
- 2002
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
48. [Untitled]
- Author
-
José María Alonso-Meijide and M. Gloria Fiestras-Janeiro
- Subjects
Computer Science::Computer Science and Game Theory ,Property (philosophy) ,Banzhaf power index ,MathematicsofComputing_GENERAL ,Structure (category theory) ,TheoryofComputation_GENERAL ,General Decision Sciences ,Context (language use) ,Management Science and Operations Research ,Theory of computation ,Economics ,A priori and a posteriori ,Value (mathematics) ,Mathematical economics ,Quotient - Abstract
In this paper we introduce a new coalitional value in the context of TU games with an a priori system of unions, which it is called the symmetric coalitional Banzhaf value. This value satisfies the property of symmetry in the quotient game, the quotient game property, and it is a coalitional value of Banzhaf. Several characterizations are provided and two political examples illustrate the differences with respect to the Owen value and the Banzhaf–Owen value.
- Published
- 2002
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
49. Choosing Voting Systems behind the Veil of Ignorance: A Two-Tier Voting Experiment
- Author
-
Matthias Weber
- Subjects
Computer science ,media_common.quotation_subject ,ComputingMilieux_LEGALASPECTSOFCOMPUTING ,Outcome (game theory) ,Cardinal voting systems ,Power (social and political) ,Microeconomics ,Voting ,0502 economics and business ,Bullet voting ,050602 political science & public administration ,Natural (music) ,050207 economics ,Law and economics ,media_common ,Anti-plurality voting ,Banzhaf power index ,jel:C91 ,business.industry ,Disapproval voting ,Group (mathematics) ,05 social sciences ,jel:D71 ,jel:D72 ,Veil of ignorance ,Public relations ,16. Peace & justice ,Calculus of voting ,0506 political science ,Ask price ,assembly voting, EU council, Penrose's Square Root Rule, optimal voting rule ,Approval voting ,050206 economic theory ,business ,Preferential block voting - Abstract
There are many situations in which different groups make collective decisions by committee voting, with each group represented by a single person. A natural question is what voting system such a committee should use. Concepts based on voting power provide guidelines for this choice. The two most prominent concepts require the Banzhaf power index to be proportional to the square root of group size or the Shapley-Shubik power index to be proportional to group size. Instead of studying the choice of voting systems based on such theoretical concepts, in this paper, I ask which systems individuals actually prefer. To answer this question, I design a laboratory experiment in which participants choose voting systems. I find that people behind the veil of ignorance prefer voting systems following the rule of proportional Shapley-Shubik power; in front of the veil subjects pr efer voting systems benefiting their own group. Participants' choices can only partially be explained by utility maximization or other outcome based concepts.
- Published
- 2014
50. NP-completeness for calculating power indices of weighted majority games
- Author
-
Yasuko Matsui and Tomomi Matsui
- Subjects
Discrete mathematics ,Voting game ,General Computer Science ,Banzhaf power index ,NP-Complete ,media_common.quotation_subject ,Power index ,Majority logic ,Power (physics) ,Theoretical Computer Science ,Completeness (order theory) ,Voting ,NP-complete ,Game theory ,Mathematical economics ,media_common ,Mathematics ,Computer Science(all) - Abstract
In this paper, we prove that both problems for calculating the Banzhaf power index and the Shapley–Shubik power index for weighted majority games are NP-complete.
- Published
- 2001
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
Catalog
Discovery Service for Jio Institute Digital Library
For full access to our library's resources, please sign in.