It is commonly accepted that 'free markets' existed at least to some extent in the USSR during the New Economic Policy (NEP). Support for this notion comes from Lenin, Trotsky, Bukharin, Preobrazhenskii, and a whole host of other participants and commentators on the 1920s. Despite this, there is little empirical analysis of markets, free or otherwise, which can be called upon to support or refute the notion, in either Soviet or western literature. Thus the purpose of this article is to begin to investigate market behaviour in the USSR in the 1920s by focusing on commodity markets such as those for grain and manufactures, and to see to what extent they could be called 'free' markets. Correlation and regression techniques are commonly used for analysing the degree of development of markets. By subjecting price data from different regions of a country to correlation analysis a judgement can be made about whether such markets are unified, based on the axiom that in a single market similarity of price movement for a given good prevails. However, it is clearly problematic to take such a measurement as an indicator of the degree of 'freeness' of markets. Nevertheless, as capitalism requires national markets in order to function, it is one step towards an analysis of the 'freeness' of markets to analyse their degree of integration. It is certainly the case that non-integrated markets cannot be free markets in the capitalist sense, and therefore integration is a necessary but not a sufficient condition for 'freeness'. It could be argued that non-capitalist free markets could exist at a local level, and thus that integration is not a necessary condition for 'freeness'. This may be logically possible, but it is clear that when Lenin, Trotsky, and all the other commentators speak of allowing the 'free market' to exist in NEP they actually mean free markets in a capitalist sense, that is where the market mechanism operates. For this to happen, it would seem reasonable to argue that higher levels of market integration are required than the purely local. Thus, this article focuses on correlation analysis of commodity price movements in the USSR during NEP as a first step towards a more rigorous analysis of NEP markets. A perennial problem with correlation analysis is to determine what numerical result justifies the conclusion that the markets under analysis are indeed unified. To overcome this difficulty, correlation coefficients for commodity markets in the USSR are compared with corresponding coefficients for markets in the US. If Soviet markets are close to the integration levels found in the US (which is regarded as the paradigm of free trade capitalism) it seems reasonable to conclude that they were indeed unified. A danger with correlation analysis is that the presence of autocorrelation in datasets - when successive values of a time series are related rather than independent - may lead to detected correlation levels being exaggerated. To overcome this problem, differencing of the price series is used together with tests for autocorrelation. Another problem encountered is the nature of the available Soviet price data. If fixed state prices were analysed a high correlation coefficient might be expected, since the state sets these prices at a national level, but this would not mean that free or integrated markets existed in the capitalist sense. However, data are available for free, or private, markets in the USSR in the 1920s, published by bodies such as the Conjuncture Institute headed by N. D. Kondrat'ev. This was closed by the Soviet authorities towards the end of the 1920s, and thus should not be regarded as being politically biased in favour of the Soviet government. Such data were collected in good faith, and no problem arises regarding deliberate falsification for political ends, although this does not mean, of course, that the data are necessarily totally accurate. However, data for comparison are available from institutions such as Gosplan, and thus checks are possible. This investigation relates to what is usually taken to be the 'big issue' of NEP in the existing historiographical literature - the viability of a mixed economy alternative to Stalin's centrally planned industrialization policy. If no level of market integration is detected in the actual NEP economy, then an industrialization drive based on a mixed economy would have required much development of market infrastructure and culture. If, on the other hand, NEP markets were reasonably integrated, then some basic level of all-Union market infrastructure could be said to exist. This would have aided industrialization within the NEP framework. Of course, the question of whether integrated markets could have been politically acceptable to a Bolshevik leadership cannot be answered by the use of statistics. Section I tries to relate the concept of free markets to the USSR in the 1920s, while section II attempts to define a standard of comparison for correlation coefficients, and section III explores how geography might influence integration. The next section examines Soviet work on this topic written during NEP, after which section V presents an original statistical analysts of NEP price data, and section VI raises the question of the quantity of goods traded on free markets at this time. Since price data suitable for correlation analysis were difficult to locate, this article can only be a first step towards analysing NEP markets.