7 results on '"Sznycer D"'
Search Results
2. A moral trade-off system produces intuitive judgments that are rational and coherent and strike a balance between conflicting moral values.
- Author
-
Guzmán RA, Barbato MT, Sznycer D, and Cosmides L
- Subjects
- Humans, Motivation, Social Behavior, Judgment, Morals
- Abstract
How does the mind make moral judgments when the only way to satisfy one moral value is to neglect another? Moral dilemmas posed a recurrent adaptive problem for ancestral hominins, whose cooperative social life created multiple responsibilities to others. For many dilemmas, striking a balance between two conflicting values (a compromise judgment) would have promoted fitness better than neglecting one value to fully satisfy the other (an extreme judgment). We propose that natural selection favored the evolution of a cognitive system designed for making trade-offs between conflicting moral values. Its nonconscious computations respond to dilemmas by constructing "rightness functions": temporary representations specific to the situation at hand. A rightness function represents, in compact form, an ordering of all the solutions that the mind can conceive of (whether feasible or not) in terms of moral rightness. An optimizing algorithm selects, among the feasible solutions, one with the highest level of rightness. The moral trade-off system hypothesis makes various novel predictions: People make compromise judgments, judgments respond to incentives, judgments respect the axioms of rational choice, and judgments respond coherently to morally relevant variables (such as willingness, fairness, and reciprocity). We successfully tested these predictions using a new trolley-like dilemma. This dilemma has two original features: It admits both extreme and compromise judgments, and it allows incentives-in this case, the human cost of saving lives-to be varied systematically. No other existing model predicts the experimental results, which contradict an influential dual-process model.
- Published
- 2022
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
3. Cross-cultural invariances in the architecture of shame.
- Author
-
Sznycer D, Xygalatas D, Agey E, Alami S, An XF, Ananyeva KI, Atkinson QD, Broitman BR, Conte TJ, Flores C, Fukushima S, Hitokoto H, Kharitonov AN, Onyishi CN, Onyishi IE, Romero PP, Schrock JM, Snodgrass JJ, Sugiyama LS, Takemura K, Townsend C, Zhuang JY, Aktipis CA, Cronk L, Cosmides L, and Tooby J
- Subjects
- Culture, Female, Humans, Male, Residence Characteristics, Social Behavior, Cross-Cultural Comparison, Shame
- Abstract
Human foragers are obligately group-living, and their high dependence on mutual aid is believed to have characterized our species' social evolution. It was therefore a central adaptive problem for our ancestors to avoid damaging the willingness of other group members to render them assistance. Cognitively, this requires a predictive map of the degree to which others would devalue the individual based on each of various possible acts. With such a map, an individual can avoid socially costly behaviors by anticipating how much audience devaluation a potential action (e.g., stealing) would cause and weigh this against the action's direct payoff (e.g., acquiring). The shame system manifests all of the functional properties required to solve this adaptive problem, with the aversive intensity of shame encoding the social cost. Previous data from three Western(ized) societies indicated that the shame evoked when the individual anticipates committing various acts closely tracks the magnitude of devaluation expressed by audiences in response to those acts. Here we report data supporting the broader claim that shame is a basic part of human biology. We conducted an experiment among 899 participants in 15 small-scale communities scattered around the world. Despite widely varying languages, cultures, and subsistence modes, shame in each community closely tracked the devaluation of local audiences (mean r = +0.84). The fact that the same pattern is encountered in such mutually remote communities suggests that shame's match to audience devaluation is a design feature crafted by selection and not a product of cultural contact or convergent cultural evolution., Competing Interests: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
- Published
- 2018
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
4. Invariances in the architecture of pride across small-scale societies.
- Author
-
Sznycer D, Xygalatas D, Alami S, An XF, Ananyeva KI, Fukushima S, Hitokoto H, Kharitonov AN, Koster JM, Onyishi CN, Onyishi IE, Romero PP, Takemura K, Zhuang JY, Cosmides L, and Tooby J
- Subjects
- Cross-Cultural Comparison, Humans, Societies, Cognition, Emotions, Social Behavior
- Abstract
Becoming valuable to fellow group members so that one would attract assistance in times of need is a major adaptive problem. To solve it, the individual needs a predictive map of the degree to which others value different acts so that, in choosing how to act, the payoff arising from others' valuation of a potential action (e.g., showing bandmates that one is a skilled forager by pursuing a hard-to-acquire prey item) can be added to the direct payoff of the action (e.g., gaining the nutrients of the prey captured). The pride system seems to incorporate all of the elements necessary to solve this adaptive problem. Importantly, data from western(-ized), educated, industrialized, rich, and democratic (WEIRD) societies indicate close quantitative correspondences between pride and the valuations of audiences. Do those results generalize beyond industrial mass societies? To find out, we conducted an experiment among 567 participants in 10 small-scale societies scattered across Central and South America, Africa, and Asia: ( i ) Bosawás Reserve, Nicaragua; ( ii ) Cotopaxi, Ecuador; ( iii ) Drâa-Tafilalet, Morocco; ( iv ) Enugu, Nigeria; ( v ) Le Morne, Mauritius; ( vi ) La Gaulette, Mauritius; ( vii ) Tuva, Russia; ( viii ) Shaanxi and Henan, China; ( ix ) farming communities in Japan; and ( x ) fishing communities in Japan. Despite widely varying languages, cultures, and subsistence modes, pride in each community closely tracked the valuation of audiences locally (mean r = +0.66) and even across communities (mean r = +0.29). This suggests that the pride system not only develops the same functional architecture everywhere but also operates with a substantial degree of universality in its content., Competing Interests: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
- Published
- 2018
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
5. Support for redistribution is shaped by compassion, envy, and self-interest, but not a taste for fairness.
- Author
-
Sznycer D, Lopez Seal MF, Sell A, Lim J, Porat R, Shalvi S, Halperin E, Cosmides L, and Tooby J
- Subjects
- Attitude, Female, Humans, India, Israel, Male, Morals, Socioeconomic Factors, United Kingdom, United States, Empathy physiology, Motivation physiology, Social Behavior, Social Welfare psychology
- Abstract
Why do people support economic redistribution? Hypotheses include inequity aversion, a moral sense that inequality is intrinsically unfair, and cultural explanations such as exposure to and assimilation of culturally transmitted ideologies. However, humans have been interacting with worse-off and better-off individuals over evolutionary time, and our motivational systems may have been naturally selected to navigate the opportunities and challenges posed by such recurrent interactions. We hypothesize that modern redistribution is perceived as an ancestral scene involving three notional players: the needy other, the better-off other, and the actor herself. We explore how three motivational systems-compassion, self-interest, and envy-guide responses to the needy other and the better-off other, and how they pattern responses to redistribution. Data from the United States, the United Kingdom, India, and Israel support this model. Endorsement of redistribution is independently predicted by dispositional compassion, dispositional envy, and the expectation of personal gain from redistribution. By contrast, a taste for fairness, in the sense of ( i ) universality in the application of laws and standards, or ( ii ) low variance in group-level payoffs, fails to predict attitudes about redistribution., Competing Interests: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
- Published
- 2017
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
6. Cross-cultural regularities in the cognitive architecture of pride.
- Author
-
Sznycer D, Al-Shawaf L, Bereby-Meyer Y, Curry OS, De Smet D, Ermer E, Kim S, Kim S, Li NP, Lopez Seal MF, McClung J, O J, Ohtsubo Y, Quillien T, Schaub M, Sell A, van Leeuwen F, Cosmides L, and Tooby J
- Subjects
- Choice Behavior, Female, Humans, Male, Motivation, Cognition, Cross-Cultural Comparison, Emotions, Social Behavior
- Abstract
Pride occurs in every known culture, appears early in development, is reliably triggered by achievements and formidability, and causes a characteristic display that is recognized everywhere. Here, we evaluate the theory that pride evolved to guide decisions relevant to pursuing actions that enhance valuation and respect for a person in the minds of others. By hypothesis, pride is a neurocomputational program tailored by selection to orchestrate cognition and behavior in the service of: ( i ) motivating the cost-effective pursuit of courses of action that would increase others' valuations and respect of the individual, ( ii ) motivating the advertisement of acts or characteristics whose recognition by others would lead them to enhance their evaluations of the individual, and ( iii ) mobilizing the individual to take advantage of the resulting enhanced social landscape. To modulate how much to invest in actions that might lead to enhanced evaluations by others, the pride system must forecast the magnitude of the evaluations the action would evoke in the audience and calibrate its activation proportionally. We tested this prediction in 16 countries across 4 continents ( n = 2,085), for 25 acts and traits. As predicted, the pride intensity for a given act or trait closely tracks the valuations of audiences, local (mean r = +0.82) and foreign (mean r = +0.75). This relationship is specific to pride and does not generalize to other positive emotions that coactivate with pride but lack its audience-recalibrating function.
- Published
- 2017
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
7. Shame closely tracks the threat of devaluation by others, even across cultures.
- Author
-
Sznycer D, Tooby J, Cosmides L, Porat R, Shalvi S, and Halperin E
- Subjects
- Cross-Cultural Comparison, Emotions physiology, Humans, India, Israel, Models, Psychological, Self Psychology, Social Perception, Stress, Psychological psychology, United States, Cognition physiology, Motivation physiology, Self Concept, Shame
- Abstract
We test the theory that shame evolved as a defense against being devalued by others. By hypothesis, shame is a neurocomputational program tailored by selection to orchestrate cognition, motivation, physiology, and behavior in the service of: (i) deterring the individual from making choices where the prospective costs of devaluation exceed the benefits, (ii) preventing negative information about the self from reaching others, and (iii) minimizing the adverse effects of devaluation when it occurs. Because the unnecessary activation of a defense is costly, the shame system should estimate the magnitude of the devaluative threat and use those estimates to cost-effectively calibrate its activation: Traits or actions that elicit more negative evaluations from others should elicit more shame. As predicted, shame closely tracks the threat of devaluation in the United States (r = .69), India (r = .79), and Israel (r = .67). Moreover, shame in each country strongly tracks devaluation in the others, suggesting that shame and devaluation are informed by a common species-wide logic of social valuation. The shame-devaluation link is also specific: Sadness and anxiety-emotions that coactivate with shame-fail to track devaluation. To our knowledge, this constitutes the first empirical demonstration of a close, specific match between shame and devaluation within and across cultures.
- Published
- 2016
- Full Text
- View/download PDF
Catalog
Discovery Service for Jio Institute Digital Library
For full access to our library's resources, please sign in.